I
I
                                                      .': '••Afjril:l983/..

 I
  i
 I
 .w
                     Benefit-Cost Assessment
                        . U.S. EPA Headquarters Library
                      •;•''"'.   . Mail code .3201.' '•"'••;
                      -' • ^ 1200'Pennsylvania Avenue NW
                      s.;" :  Washington DC 20460;  .
                                                      Programs
                                                      Volume  I
 \A



 f
 I

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
if*0
                                                                    April 1983
 I
    0-
 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

I
                                  Benefit-Cost Assessment Handbook
                                                        for Water Programs
                                                                      Volume  I
                                                                  Prepared for
                                            U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
                                                     Economic Analysis Division
                                                         Washington, DC 20460
              U.S. EPA Headquarters Library
                    Mail code 3201
              1200 Pennsylvania Avenue NW
                 Washington DC 20460
                  Prepared by
      Dr. William H. Desvousges
      Research Triangle Institute
Research Triangle Park, NC  27709
                         and
             Dr. V. Kerry Smith
     University of North Carolina
         Chapel Hill, NC  27514
                      The information in this document has been subject to the U.S. Environmental
                   Protection Agency's (EPA) Peer and Administrative Review, and it has been ap-
                   proved for publication as an EPA document. Mention of trade names or com-
                   mercial products does not constitute endorsement or recommendation for use.

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
i
i
                                                 April 1983
        Benefit-Cost Assessment Handbook
                               for Water Programs
                                             Volume I
                                               Prepared for
                         U.S. Environmental Protection Asency
                               •   Economic Analysis Division
                                      Washington, DC 20460
                                               Prepared by
                                   Dr. William H. Desvousses
                                    Research Triansle Institute
                             Research Triansle Park, NC 27709
                                                      and
                                          Dr. V. Kerry Smith
                                  University of North Carolina
                                      Chapel Hill, NC 27514
   The information in this document has been subject to the U.S. Environmental
Protection Agency's (EPA) Peer and Administrative Review, and it has been ap-
proved for publication as an EPA document. Mention of trade names or com-
mercial products does not constitute endorsement or recommendation for use.

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
 I
 I
 I
                                  PREFACE

     As  one component of the decision  process,  water program offices at the
 Federal, State, and  local levels  along  with  advisory citizen groups have per-
 ceived the  need to consider the beneficial  and detrimental  effects of policies
 that  affect water  quality.   In response, the U.S.  Environmental Protection
 Agency's Office of Policy Analysis sponsored  the development of this Benefit-
 Cost  Assessment  Handbook for Water Programs.   This experimental  handbook
 will  not  short-circuit any Federal, State, or local  water quality laws.   Rather,
 It provides suggestions about  how to evaluate the economic aspects of a pro-
 posed  policy as a regular part of the decision process.  These evaluations can
 identify  water quality  policies  that  have highest priority, so  that  society's
 resources  can  be  directed  to  the areas that  will have the  greatest benefits.
 They also can  serve  as one of  several analyses that support the decision proc-
 ess for  any specific  water  quality  policy.   Such  ah approach  can help assure
 the attainment of our  Nation's water quality goals with a minimum expenditure
 of resources.

     The Benefit-Cost  Assessment Handbook for  Water Programs is a  primer.
 It assumes only a limited familiarity with economics.  Throughout the handbook,
 case studies help to clarify points.   Data needs,  key assumptions, and other
 relevant points are covered for different ways of determining  the relationship
 between  desirable and undesirable effects of a program decision.

     Since  water program  offices  have begun to  move  toward  the  use  of
 benefit-cost concepts,  the scope of  the  handbook is broad  enough to explain
 how  to conduct  benefit-cost assessments in diverse applications.  The costs
 and  health  benefits of drinking water  policies  are covered  elsewhere, so this
 handbook concentrates  on the benefits  and  costs for other water programs.
 Although most  of the examples  in this volume are  for hypothetical water quality
 standards  decisions,  the  tools  can  be  applied to a broad spectrum of  water
quality decisions, and even to environmental issues in general.

     If there  is  sufficient  interest  in  this  experimental  approach,  a second
volume may be developed to provide more in-depth discussion of the benefit-
cost  assessment for use by practitioners.  It  also may be  desirable to tailor a
similar document for specific  water  programs.  The Office of Policy  Analysis
welcomes comments and  suggestions, which may be  directed to:

               Ann Fisher
               U.S. Environmental Protection Agency
               401 M Street, S.W.
               Office of Policy Analysis  (PM-220)
               Washington, D.C.  20460
               (202) 382-2783
                                     iii

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                         ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

     Why are the acknowledgments always the last section to be written
in any  report?  This question,  which often .occurs on the way to work
toward  the end of a project,  is  likely  one  without  a definite answer.
We could surmise that  it comes from an unwillingness to let go at the
end  of  any project  (not  likely) or simply that we have saved the best
for last.
                                     "i
     We are indebted to  many  people who have  given of their time to
assist  us  in  writing this handbook.  Yet there is  one person whose
commitment to the  project  stands out.  That  person  is  our project
officer  at the Environmental  Protection Agency (EPA), Dr. Ann Fisher.
The simple truth is that without Ann Fisher this handbook would not
have been written.  With the many hours she has given to  the project
she  is  more author  than  anything else.   Since  she  would never have
allowed  this acknowledgment to appear  .in the report had she read it,
perhaps this is the reason for leaving it until  last.

     As this  handbook  has evolved, it  has  drawn from many  sources.
Chapter 4 pertaining to the costs of regulatory  actions draws heavily
on an earlier  chapter prepared  by Metasystems,  Inc., and particularly
Tze-Wen  Chi  and Peter  Morgan.  Indeed,  most of  the examples  are
taken from this  earlier draft.   Assistance  on the  cost chapter came
from the Office of Analysis  and Evaluation under Louis Dupuis.  John
Kukulka and Joe Yance from the staff suggested many helpful  revisions
in support of  the project.

     Office of Policy Analysis staff members provided valuable detailed
critiques  of early drafts.  Reed Johnson, Bob Raucher, Peter Caulkins,
and  Skip Luken  gave good counsel.  Joan O'Callaghan's valuable edi-
torial suggestions on an  early  draft have been  incorporated  into this
draft.

     The EPA staff in the  water program  area have  also played an
important  role  in this  project.   Patrick Tobin, Dave Sabock, xand
Marjorie Pitts  of the Office of Water Regulations  and Standards,  Myron
Temins  and Charles Moar of the  Office of Water Programs  Operations
(OWPO),  and Jerry Manorola,   formerly of OWPO,  gave  extensive
comments.

     In  addition,  helpful comments were  received from Dan Huppert,
MNFS Southwest  Fisheries Service; Robin Gottfried, University  of the
South;  John  Luensman,  Department of  Planning  and Development,
Chautauqua County, New York;  John  Loomis,  U.S.  Forest  Service;
and Mike Piette, University, of Hartford.
                                 v

-------

     Finally, the RTI  staff has been most supportive.  Tayler Bingham
brought  his  experienced view of environmental  regulations to bear on
all  of the  drafts of this handbook.  Tayler's insightful comments are
valued , highly.   Hall  Ashmore's editorial  efforts mark every  page of
this handbook.   Hall's economy  with  words  and his ability to make an
author's  prose  bear  fruit  are  assets for  any handbook or report.
Finally,  Jan  Shirley  and the  Institute's  Word  Processing Specialists
have done  yet another outstanding  job of  producing a  pleasing report.
Jan's devotion to  quality and  her ability to know when  to coax or
cajole a reluctant writer are most appreciated.
                                  VI

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                CONTENTS

Chapter                                                              Page

   1     BENEFIT-COST ASSESSMENT:  A  COMMON
        SENSE APPROACH TO DECISIONS	1-1

        1.1   introduction	1-1

        1.2   Regulation:  An Overview	1-2

        1.3   Benefits:  An  Economic View	1-4

        1.4   Costs:   An Economic View	1-5

        1.5   Benefit-Cost Assessement:  What Is It?	1-6

              .Is  Benefit-Cost Assessment Different
              from Cost-Benefit Analysis?	1-6

              Benefit-Cost Assessment: ' A Step-by-
              Step View	1-7

        1.6   Key Considerations in an Assessment	1-11

        1.7   Summary	   1-12

        1.8   Guide to Handbook	1-13


   2     ISSUES IN A BENEFIT-COST ASSESSMENT	2-1

        2.1   Introduction	2-1

        2.2   Including Intangibles in a Benefit-Cost
              Assessment	2-1

              Introduction	2-1

            .  Example	2-2

        2.3   Economic Impact Measures	2-5

              Assessing  Household  Impacts	2-5

               .Ability to Pay  	2-5

                 Financial Capability    	2-6

            •  Assessing  Industrial  Impacts	2-6

              Assessing Changes in Employment,
              Output, and Prices	2-6

        2.4   What to Do About Distribution:  Problems
              in Adding  up Over People	   2-7
                                    VII

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                           CONTENTS (continued)


Chapter

              Introduction	2-7

              Example  I	  2-8

              Example  II.	2-9

              Summary:  Distribution  	2-9

        2.5   Discounting Future Benefits and Costs:
              Adding up Over Time	  .  2-10

              Time Preference:  What Is  It?	2-11

              How To Determine the Discount Rate in
              a Less Than  Ideal World	2-12

              Including Risk  in an Assessment of
              Discount Rates    	2-14

              What Are the Empirical Implications of
              the Discount Rate Issues?	  2-15

              The Simple Mechanics of  Discounting .	2-16

              Discounting:  A Summary Review   	2-18

        2.6   Summary	2-19


   3     MEASURING THE BENEFITS OF WATER
        QUALITY PROGRAMS   	3-1

        3.1   .Introduction    	3-1

        3,2   Categories  of Benefits:  Ah
              Overview	3-1

        3.3   Practical  Concerns:  Selecting a Benefit
              Estimation Method	  3-4

        3.4   Household Benefits	:	3-5

              Theory:  The Demand  Function	"	3-5

              Practice:  Methods for Measuring
              Household Benefits	• 3-6

              Travel  Cost Method  .'	3-6

                 Data  Needs and Key Assumptions and
                 Features	3-8

                 Case Study:   Alternative Approaches  for
                 Estimating Recreation and  Related Benefits
                 of the Monongahela  River	.  3-9
                                    viii

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                           CONTENTS  (continued)

Chapter

              Survey-Contingent Valuation	-.  .  .  .   3-14

                 Data Needs, Key Assumptions/
                 Limitations,  and Features   	3-16

                 Case Study:   Recreation and Related Benefits
                 of Water Quality Improvements in the
                 Mondngahela River	3-18

              Survey—Recreation Participation Models	3-20

                 Data Needs, Key Assumptions/
                 Limitations,  and Features	   3-21

                 Case Study:   A Participation Survey
                 Approach to Valuing Water Quality
                 Improvements	3-22

              Hedonic Property Value Method   	3-25

                 Data Needs, Key Assumptions/
                 Limitations,  and Features   	3-26

             . Damage Function  Method	3-27

                 Data Needs, Key Assumptions/
                 Limitations,  and Features   	3-27

        3.5   Business Benefits	3-27

              Theory:  The Supply Function	3-27

              Practice:  Cost Savings Function Method for
              Measuring Business Benefits	3-28

                 Data Needs, Key Assumptions/
                 Limitations,  and Features   .	3-29

                 Case Study:   Irrigation Benefits  . .  .	3-30

        3.6   Public Water Supply Benefits	3-32

        3.7   Summary	3-32


  4     MEASURING THE COSTS  OF WATER QUALITY
        PROGRAMS   	4-1

        4.1   Introduction    	4-1

        4.2   Measuring Costs:   The Basic Concepts	4-1

        4.3   Measuring Costs:   Two General Approaches  .......   4-3

        4.4   Types of Costs	4-4

              Capital Costs     '.	4-4
                                     IX

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                           .CONTENTS (continued)
Chapter
              Operation and Maintenance Costs	4-5

              Reinvestment Costs	4-6

              Salvage Value	'.  4-6

              Summary Cost Measures	4-8

        4.5   Practical Issues in Measuring Costs	4-8

              Sources of Cost Data  	4-8

              The  Use of Cost Indexes	4-9

              Major Factors Affecting Cost Estimates   	4-11

              Sample Data Form	4-12

        4.6   Cost Estimating Techniques   	4-12

              Components of  Treatment  Systems	4-12

              Estimating treatment Costs	4-15

        4.7   Examples Using Cost Techniques	  4-17

              Example 1:  Pulp Mill Using EPA Development
              Document	4-17

              Example 2:  POTW Using CAPDET	4-21

              Example 3:  POTW Using Technology
              Assessment Manual   .	4-25

              Example 4:  What to Do When There Is
              "No  Information"	4-25

        4.8   Final Cautions	4-27

        4.9   Summary	4-27


   5     COMPLETING THE BENEFIT-COST ASSESSMENT	5-1

        5.1   Introduction    	5-1

        5.2   Sensitivity  Analysis:  A Gauge  to Believability    ....  5-1

              Introduction	5-1

              Example	5-3

              Step 1:   Translate the Benefits  and
              Costs into Present Values	5-3

              Step 2:   Perform Sensitivity Analysis for
              Discount Rate and  Key Assumptions	5-4

              Step 3:   Interpret Sensitivity Analysis   	5-4

-------

                           CONTENTS (continued)
Chapter                                                              Page
        5.3   Displaying the Assessment  Results	5-4
              Narratives	5-6
              Arrays	5-6
              Graphs	•.	5-6
        5.4   Benefit-Cost Assessment  Checklist .  .  .  .-	5-9
        5.5   Summary	5-9

   6    BENEFIT-COST--SAMPLE  SCENARIOS	6-1
        6.1   Introduction   	6-1
        6.2   Simple Case  Scenario	6-2
              Introduction   	6-2
              Simple Case  Scenario Format  .	6-2
        6.3   Medium Case Scenario	6-4
              .Introduction   	6-4
              Medium Case Scenario Format. .  . . '	6-5
        6.4   Complex Case Scenario	6-6
              Introduction   	6-6
              Complex Case Scenario Format	.' .  .   6-7
        6.5   Summary	6-26

   7    References	7-1
                                     XI

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                   FIGURES

Number

   1-1    Effects and responses to water quality
         regulatory actions    	1-2

   1-2    Key steps in a benefit-cost assessment	.'....  1-9

   1-3    Key steps in a complex  benefit-cost
         assessment .	1-10


   3-1    A spectrum of  water quality benefits	  3-2

   3-2    The demand function and consumer surplus	3-5

   3-3    Illustration of the treatment of water quality
         with travel cost demand model	3-7

   3-4    General travel  cost  demand model for a water
         quality improvement	3-13

   3-5    Supply .function and the producer surplus	3-28

   3-6    Irrigation benefits	'	3-30


   4-1    Measurement of opportunity/costs   	4-2

   4-2    Sample model plant data form   	4-13


   5-1    Tradeoff curve.	5-7

   5-2    Checklist for a water quality standards
         benefit-cost assessment	  5-8


   6-1    Travel cost demand  function and  consumer
         surplus with boatable water	6-10

   6-2    Travel cost demand  function and  change  in
         consumer surplus with fishable water   	6-12

   6-3   Travel cost demand  function and  change  in
         consumer surplus with swimmable water   .  .	6-16
                                     XIII

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Number

   2-1


   2-2


   2-3


   2-4

   2-5

   2-6
                                   TABLES
Benefits and Costs of Attaining Fish and
Wildlife Use:  Array   1	  2-3

Benefits and Costs of Attaining Fish and
Wildlife Use:  Array 2	  .  2-3

Benefits and Costs of Attaining Fish and
Wildlife Use:  Array 3	2-4

Summary of Industrial Impact Measures	2-7

Distribution of Benefits and Costs   	2-9

Summary of Final  Description Factors
Influencing  Shadow Price of Capital	2-13
   3-1    Classification of  Benefit Categories   	3-3

   3-2    Site Attributes Considered in  Monongahela
         River Study	3-11

   3-3    Estimated Equations for Site Demand  Parameter
         Estimates     	
                                                              3-11
   3-4   Specifications for the Dissolved Oxygen
        (DO) Levels Associated  With  Use Designations	3-12

   3-5   Benefit Estimates from Generalized Travel
        Cost Model  With  the Monongahela Survey
        Respondents	   3-14

   3-6   Summary  of Biases in Contingent Valuation
        Experiments	3-17

   3-7   Willingness  to Pay for Three  Levels of
        Water Quality	3-19

   3-8   Vaughan-Russell Model—Predicted Effects
        of BPT Regulations on Participation   .	3-24


   4-1   Components of Capital and .Operation  and
        Maintenance Costs	4-5

   4-2   Variables  and Definitions for  Measuring Costs	4-7

   4-3   Example 1:  Cost Summary-Market Bleached
        Kraft, Subcategory   	4-18
                                     xv

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                             TABLES  (continued)
Number
   4-4   Example 2:   Current and Upgraded Treatment
         Trains  for CAPDET	  .   4-22

   4-5   Example 2:   Price and  Cost Inputs to CAPDET	4-23

   4-6   Example 2:   POTW Upgrading  Cost Summary	4-24

   4-7   Example .3:   Development of Capital Costs
         (Nitrification)    	4-26

   4-8   Example 3:   Summary of Costs for Nitrification
         Upgrade	   4-26


   5-1    Key Elements of  Benefits and  Costs  . .'	5-2

   5-2   Sensitivity Analysis Calculations:  Discount
         Rate at 4 percent	 . .	5-5

   5-3   Sensitivity Analysis    	5-5



   6-1    Demand for Recreation  for  River 1--Water
         Quality at  Level  Suitable for Boating   	6-9

   6-2    Demand for Recreation  for  River 1--Water  .
         Quality at  Level  Where  Gamefish  (Bass) Can
         Live in River	6-11

   6-3    Capital  Equipment and  Cost for Model Plant
         to Meet Regulation	•	6-17

   6-4    Estimated Capital Costs  	6-18

   6-5    Cost of Treatment Plant, City  B	6-18

   6-6    Present Value of Benefits	  .   6-22

   6-7    Present Value of Operating Costs	6-23

   6-8   Total  Project Costs     	'	6-23

   6-9    Benefits and Costs of Attaining Fish  and
        Wildlife  Propagation  Use Designation    	6-24

   6-10  Distribution of Benefits and Costs    	6-25
                                     XVJ

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                  CHAPTER 1

                   BENEFIT-COST ASSESSMENT:  A COMMON
                      SENSE APPROACH TO DECISIONS
1.1  INTRODUCTION

     Should  a State  change the designation of impaired uses for a river?  Will
a  sewer overflow  project .provide  benefits  in  excess of costs?  Is advanced
waste  treatment  necessary to  attain a  river's designated  uses?  Are treatment
plants more desirable on some rivers.than on others?

     This  handbook—a primer on benefit-cost assessment—shows how economic
principles  can help  decisionmakers make these difficult choices.   Its primary
intent is to  demonstrate  the  common  sense inherent in  benefit-cost  assess-
ments  of alternative choices.  In  addition, this handbook  shows how  to add an
economic dimension to  scientific and technical analyses in considering the full
range of impacts  from a proposed water quality action.

     Since they  focus  on  the  alternatives available to society, economic prin-
ciples  are  especially  relevant to water quality program problems.  Specifically,
the  economic viewpoint  recognizes  that  the  scarcity  of society's  resources
forces choices  among  alternatives.   However,  choosing among alternatives
creates tradeoffs—i.e., one thing must be  given  up to attain another.  Thus,
water  quality decisions  produce  both  desired   and  undesired  effects  for
society.   Benefit-cost assessment simply  uses economic principles to help  the
decisionmaker make these choices.

     Water quality programs implement  regulatory mandates or provide assist-
ance  either  to  those  adversely  affected  by the regulations  or for specific
projects.  Principles covered in this handbook could be applied to:

          Effluent guidelines issues that  require  limits on specific indus-
          trial discharges.

          Water quality standards issues  where States designate uses for
          water bodies and develop criteria to achieve the uses.

          Advanced treatment  issues  where  the Federal Government  pro-
          vides   financial  assistance  to  construct  municipal   treatment
          plants that require advanced technologies.

          Combined-sewer overflow  issues   where Federal  assistance  is
          provided to  deal  with  municipal  runoffs that  create pollution
          problems.
                                      1-1

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
      This chapter discusses the basic  principles  in  a benefit-cost assessment.
Specifically,  Section  1.2 provides  an  overview of  regulation,  using  linkages
between  regulatory  actions, effects,  and  changes  in behavior.  To  highlight
the  basic principles, Section 1.3 describes .benefits from an .economic perspec-
tive,  and  Section 1.4  details  a similar  discussion for  costs.  The basic  con-
cepts of benefit-cost assessment are  described  in  Section 1.5,  along with  a
step-by-step  view of an assessment.  Section  1.6 gives  some  groundrules for
performing an assessment  and Section  1.7 summarizes  the  key points in  the
chapter.   Finally, Section 1.8  provides  a guide to  the  remainder  of Volume I
of the handbook.

1.2   REGULATION:  AN OVERVIEW

      Understanding  how benefit-cost assessments can  be  used  is easier  with
some  knowledge  of  how  a  regulation affects economic  activities.  The key to
this  understanding is the linkage (shown in Figure  1-1) between (1)  a change
in a regulation (an action), (2) its technical  effects,  and  (3.) the behavioral
responses to  it.
                Water Quality
                Regulatory Action(s)"
                                         Change Designated Use(s)
                                         Modify Criteria to Provide
                                           for Designated Use(s)
                Technical Effects
                of Water Quality  —-
                Rcgulatory Action(s)
                                           Changes in Effluents
                                         Changes in Water Quality
                                           Change in Ecological
                                               Habitat
                                           Effect* on Economic
                                               Agents
                Behavioral Effects   I
                of Water Quality   _j
                Regulatory Action(s) |	
Behavioral Responses
of Economic Agents
            Figure 1-1. Effects and responses to water quality regulatory actions.
                                        1-2

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
      One  example of an action represented by the first two  blocks in  Figure
 1-1  is a change in  the uses designated for a  water body  and the associated
 modifications of  technical water  quality  criteria to accommodate these  uses.
 The  action changes  effluent levels and  the  resulting water quality  and ecolog-
 ical  habitat—all of which affect households and businesses, the primary eco-
 nomic agents.  A change in effluent levels  simply  means more or fewer  pollut-
 ants  will  be discharged into the water  body,  thus altering overall  water qual-
 ity.  The  changes in water quality alter the diversity of microorganisms, fish,
 or flora and fauna and can noticeably change  the local ecological habitat.  The
 magnitude of the technical effects depends on  specific water body characteris-
 tics,  the  nature of  the pollutant being controlled, and the extent  of control.
 For  example,  river  depth,  flowrate, and riverbed  geology will influence the
 technical effects of changing the designated uses of  a river to include a warm-
 water fishery.

      Not all water quality  programs are regulatory programs.  For example,
 the combined sewer  overflow (CSO)  program  aims at directly  enhancing water
 quality  by reducing  the surge of pollutants  following a severe storm.   Even
 in these programs, a determination of the linkages between the  project and its
 technical effects is essential.

      Equally important to benefit-cost assessment is how businesses and  house-
 holds  are  affected by the action.  For  example, if improved water  quality will
 support a  warmwater fishery in a watercourse, more  gamefish will likely inhabit
 the river,  thus enabling fishermen  'to catch more fish--the  technical effect on
 the household.   However,  to achieve the level  of  dissolved oxygen necessary
 to support gamefish,  regulation might be required  so that firms clean  up their
 discharges into the  river.   From society's viewpoint, therefore, actions have '
 both  beneficial  and  detrimental effects.   Maximizing  the public good  requires
 consideration of both types of effects.

     Determining how beneficial and  detrimental  effects balance out  requires
 consideration of the final  linkage—how  primary  economic agents change their
 behavior  in response  to technical effects.  For example, if the technical ef-
 fects  of a water  regulation (e.g., an  increase in  gamefish  populations) allow
 fishermen  currently  using a  watercourse to  use  it  more,  new users may be
 attracted to the  site.   In economic  terms, this situation is described  as in-
 creased  demand for  a  site's  recreation  services.  The amount  of the demand
 increase will be determined both  by site attributes (features) and  by the site
 users.   Important site  attributes include the  proximity  of substitute fishing
 streams, the number of access  points,  and the quality of local natural fea-
 tures, such as  the surrounding countryside.   The incomes of the  fishermen,
 the price of fishing  equipment, and  how  badly the  users  and potential  users
 want to fish—their preferences for fishing—will also  affect the ultimate behav-
 ioral response to increased gamefish populations.

     However,  just as households (or fishermen, as in  the example)  respond
 to the  technical  effects of  regulatory  actions,  firms  also  respond.  Specif-
 ically, they  may decide  to close down  operations,  alter waste treatment proc-
 esses, or  alter  product  mixes  to  meet  the technical  standard  required by the
decision.   Clearly,  each of  these  behavioral  responses  has different conse-
                                    1-3

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 quences, but  the  magnitude of the regulation's technical effects  is determined
 by the  range of  feasible  responses and  the market conditions for the goods
 produced  by  the  affected  businesses.   Thus,  firms facing  more  favorable
 market  conditions  find  a  wider  range  of choices open  to  them,  and those
 facing strong pressures from competing firms  are more limited.

     The actual  regulatory process  is considerably more complex  and less cer-
 tain than indicated above.   For  example,  businesses using  water  in  their
 production  process could  be adversely  affected  by the  regulation  if higher
 dissolved oxygen  levels  corrode their water pipes, resulting  in higher  operat-
 ing  costs.   Similarly,  individuals  who  are not users  of  the site  may be  af-
 fected  if they view general increased ecological  diversity as a  beneficial  ef-
 fect.  In the  end, therefore,  practitioners  will  have  to  determine which  ef-
 fects are relevant for inclusion in the benefit-cost assessment.

     More importantly,  the  linkages discussed  in this section  do  not attach
 values  to the positive  and  negative effects.   Rather, they  merely suggest a
 way of viewing the regulatory process to help determine what the effects are.
 In some cases, however, the decision process is eased  if effects are converted
 to values.  Unfortunately,  the attachment of  values to the effects is a trouble-
 some process for many potential  users of benefit-cost assessment.

 1.3  BENEFITS:  AN ECONOMIC VIEW  '

     The economic approach  to  defining  and measuring regulatory  benefits is
 unfamiliar to  many noneconomists.   Quite  simply,  however,  economics  ap-
 proaches benefits  from  society's perspective, assigning values based on  indi-
 viduals'  willingness  to   pay  for particular regulatory effects.*   In essence,
 economics implicitly assumes  individuals are best suited to value the effects of
 water quality programs.

     Once both the beneficial and  detrimental effects of a proposed  action have
 been  identified,  the practitioner may heed to  weigh their relative  importance
 before  a final decision  is made.   Of course,  the economic  valuing process
 described above  can help determine  relative importance--e.g., area  fishermen's
 willingness to  pay for an action to increase gamefish populations vs.  the costs
 incurred by  a  local industrial plant  whose discharges the action will require be
 cleaned up—but  it has limits.  Indeed,  no approach—economic or  otherwise—is
 a  substitute  for  the  judgment that decisionmakers  must  exercise to make
 choices among alternatives representing various  types and  degrees of well-
 being  to  a variety of population subgroups  (fishermen, plant  owners, etc.).
 Benefit-cost  assessment  is  a  framework for identifying  and organizing informa-
 tion to ease the decisionmaking process, not a decision rule.
     *lt should  be recognized,  however,  that,  added  up  over all  persons,
individual  willingness  to pay is influenced  by the income, or wealth, available
to each person.
                                    1-4

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
      One frequently asked question  is,  "Why do  people have to 'pay' for the
 beneficial effects of water quality programs?"  The answer is that they do not;
 alternatively,  they could accept payment to forgo the effects.  In effect, the
 two measures—willingness to pay and  willingness  to accept—are equally good,
 but different,  measures.  While the  "accept"  measure  implicitly assumes the
 individual  "owns"  the  rights to the  beneficial  change, the  "pay" measure
 assumes the  opposite.   Volume II  of the handbook will discuss how benefits
 based on these two different measures can be related.   The important distinc-
 tion is the equity  question--!.e.,  whether  individuals  own  rights to the pro-
 gram benefits.

      Although willingness  to  accept is  an equally  good  measure, willingness to
 pay is normally used to discuss regulatory benefits because  it can be revealed
 in  markets, when they  exist, through  purchases of good's/or services affected
 by the program.  Then, benefits can be  measured empirically.  Although these
 markets  clearly  do  not  exist for the  effects of  water quality  improvements,
 willingness  to pay is  still  a useful  way of valuing benefits.  An  assessment
 may describe  benefits only  in  qualitative terms,  but  the  description can  be
 written from  the perspective of willingness  to pay.  The benefits measurement
 approaches  discussed in Chapter 3  are ways that economists have approached
 the benefits  problem when  markets  do  not exist.  None of these approaches
 gives  precise  estimates  of  willingness  to pay.   Each  is a blunt tool,  capable
 only of giving  rough estimates, which are sufficient in most cases.

 1.4 COSTS:   AN ECONOMIC VIEW

     Opportunity cost  measures  the cost of any resource--e.g.,  labor, ma-
 chinery,  environmental  resources—in terms of  its next best alternative  use.
 That is,  the  value of forgone alternative uses  of any  resource provides  the
 basis for estimating the  cost of any specific use.  As a result,  opportunity
 cost considers  tradeoffs—i.e.,  how  much must  be given up of one thing to
 have more of another.

     For  example,  assume a  proposed  project would  improve  a lake's  water
 quality to permit recreational fishing,  boating,  and swimming.   The lake can-
 hot now  support any of these activities,  but it would if quality were improved
 by  constructing  a waste treatment plant  along a river  that feeds the lake.   In
 this example,  the opportunity costs of  the action would be the forgone op-
 portunities  of  all the resources used  in  improving water quality.   In the ab-
 sence  of  market  imperfections,  the opportunity cost of construction inputs—
 equipment,  materials,  labor,  land,  etc.--would  be  valued  by  their market
 prices.   In  addition, if the action  precludes use  of the  river or the lake for
other activities (such as  industrial or  agricultural uses), the values of these
forgone alternatives would also be part of the opportunity costs.

     Many  practitioners consider cost  estimation  an  easier  task than benefit
estimation.  Perhaps a  more  accurate view is that many find  it less objection-
able to  value  the  labor,  materials, and equipment used  as a  result  of an
action.   However,  difficulties can arise  when the full  social costs  of the  in-
vestment alternatives are considered, or when effects on rates of technological
change are  included.  Cost estimation is likely to involve as many judgments
                                    1-5

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
 I
I
 as benefit estimation  and is subject to the  same general cautions.  Indeed,
 caution  is advised in making too great a case  for  precision in  the measurement
 of economic well-being when  less precision than desired exists in  the  linkage
 between the regulatory action and its effect on economic activities.   The prob-
 lems in establishing  linkages  do not  imply  these technical  issues should .be
 ignored, only that they  be  considered  in  their proper perspective—as a part
 of the  problem of evaluating the benefits  and costs associated with a  change
 in water quality.

 1,5  BENEFIT-COST ASSESSMENT:  WHAT  IS  IT?

      Benefit-cost assessment  is a way of organizing  information—a method for
 identifying all  the favorable and unfavorable outcomes of a proposed  action.
 Where  necessary for complex decisions, many of  these outcomes can be con-
 verted  into a  common  set of units  (usually dollars)  to permit consistent com-
 parisions of benefits and costs.  Monetization may be  impossible for outcomes
 which defy measurement.   Even  in  these  cases,  the  benefit-cost assessment
 framework  can  organize  information  associated  with  an  action.   In  short,
 benefit-cost assessment is a  practical method  for  including  basic economic
 principles in the decision process.

      Although benefit-cost  assessment  is a guide to  decisionmakers, it does
 not  provide the final  answer to a public policy decision.   Other factors such
 as the  public's  view  of appropriate uses  for a particular water body  or the
 fairness  of cost impacts on  particular groups  are  important  considerations.
 What a .benefit-cost assessment  does do  is provide  an organizing  framework
 for  information the  public  and  rulemaking body  can use in making more in-
 formed  decisions.

      It  is important to recognize that  value judgments are a  part  of all deci-
 sions.  Benefit-cost assessments  supplement  scientific and technical informa-
 tion with economic  information that may help  decisionmakers make these judg-
 ments.   Very  simply,  a  well-structured  benefit-cost  assessment can  reduce
 the  complexity  of what needs to be considered,  making the decision process
 more manageable.

 Is Benefit-Cost Assessment Different from Cost-Benefit Analysis?

     One of the first  things that comes to mind for potential practitioners of
 benefit-cost assessment is  the past misuse  of  cost-benefit  analysis.  These
 misuses  emphasized the search  for a ratio—the  one "number"--that would ra-
 tionalize or justify a  project.   In  many  instances,  the  misuses involved  an
 attempt to include benefits that  were, at best, marginally related  to a project.
 This  is  not the case  for  the  benefit-cost assessment suggested in  this hand-
 book.   Since  benefit-cost assessment requires a  consistent, systematic treat-
 ment of benefits  and  costs, an outside observer  can  easily  discover when  a
 practitioner tries to stretch  the approach  beyond  the  limits dictated by com-
 mon   sense.   When  the  assessment process  is  carefully  conducted, common
 sense will provide  a  reasonable guide  through  most of the  decisions.   Any-
thing not  sensible should  be scrutinized.  Critics who maintain that benefit-
cost assessment  can be used to  justify anything  overlook the fact that any
approach can be abused.


                                    1-6

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
     Since  it can compare benefits and costs in qualitative terms, in qualita-
 tive terms with  some quantification,  in  quantitative terms,  or in monetized
 terms,  benefit-cost  assessment is a more flexible  approach than  conventional
 cost-benefit analysis.  The key,  of  course,  is  the nature of the  decision.  A
 qualitative  assessment will  reveal  whether the  potential  benefits and  costs  at
 stake  in  a water quality decision are clearcut. No further economic  assess-
 ment will  be  needed,  yet the decisionmaker will  have a  logical,  consistent
 basis for economic  considerations.  If  the situation is more complicated, or if
 the  potential  benefits  and costs at stake are considerably larger, a more de-
 tailed benefit-cost assessment can  make the decision  more manageable.

     Many  ways exist to tailor a benefit-cost assessment to  fit the needs  of
 the  Issue at hand.   For example, monetization  can  play a critical  role  in more
 complicated benefit-cost assessment decisions.  Specifically, by blending mone-
 tization  with  qualitative  judgment,  .benefit-cost - assessment  can  determine
 whether the benefits bear a reasonable relationship to the costs involved and
 whether there will  be significant  impacts  on  certain parts of the population  or
 the economy.

     A  misconception that arises  with  benefit-cost  assessment  involves  recent
 techniques—such as  survey techniques—developed to  deal  with previously
 immeasurable or  nonmonetizable benefits, such as  enhanced ecological  diver-
 sity or amenities.   These survey  techniques  are not opinion  polls; they  rely
 on  carefully designed  questionnaires to measure an individual's willingness  to
 pay for these  benefits.   One  fact has been  clearly shown  by all  the survey
 studies:  such  previously  nonquantifiable  benefits  are indeed a substantial
 component of the total environmental  benefits  picture.  That  is, the  studies
 have shown these benefits to be large,  and an assessment that overlooks them
 may indeed  understate the  full  benefits. While most water quality  decisions
 will  not require a survey to determine these previously  nonquantifiable bene-
 fits,  some  benefit-cost assessments  may  adapt  the results  of  recent  surveys
for specific  sites (e.g.,  see  Chapter 6,   Section 6.3).   A few instances  may
occur  in  which,  because the  potential costs are  so  large, practitioners  may
want to use simple  surveys to get at least a ball park estimate of  such poten-
tial benefits.

Benefit-Cost Assessment:  A Step-by-Step View

     Each  of  us makes decisions  every day,  judging whether  the anticipated
consequences  of an  action will be "worth" the "costs."   Of  course, the mean-
ings of "worth"  and "costs" vary from one person  to  the next  because differ-
ent people evaluate  the same action  differently. Whatever the outcome, how-
ever, the  logic  underlying the decision  process is the  same.   Based on  this
decision logic,  benefit-cost assessment is a  method for  defining "worth"  and
"costs," offering  a  logical framework for  structuring  information for  decisions
in the public sector.

     Although  performing a  benefit-cost  assessment is  not  a mechanical task
with each step completely known in advance,  it  is  possible to outline the gen-
eral  steps  that  are  useful in assembling  a complete assessment.   These steps
                                    1-7

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 flesh  out the linkages  between  a  policy decision and  the behavioral  changes,
 highlighted  earlier  in  Figure 1-1.   For instance, an  assessment  can portray
 the individuals and  firms that will be directly affected by a  regulatory  action,
 how they will be affected, and how they will  change their behavior in response
 to the regulation.

      The logic of a benefit-cost  assessment is straightforward, as  shown in
 the following steps:

           Define the action

           Determine an appropriate approach based on resources or  com-
           plexity of  the action

           Identify and estimate the incremental benefits of the action

           Identify and estimate the incremental costs of the action

           Compare the benefits and costs of the  action

           Assess the plausibility of the results

           Highlight  the  distribution of  benefits  and costs and financial
           impacts of the action

           Integrate  the  assessment  into other  aspects  of  the  decision-
           making process.                                               .

      For example,  Figure 1-2 illustrates these steps for a water  quality  stand-
 ards   action,  such   as  a  State's changing the uses  designated for a river
 segment.  Steps in  the upper portion of Figure 1-1 assemble and organize the
 available data for the  change in  designated uses.  The optional  analyses of
 the technical aspects of a water quality standards  decision—analyses for  use
 attainability, site-specific  criteria,  and  wasteload allocation—can  be valuable
 sources  of data on  the technical linkages  between  an action arid  its effects.
 By sorting the data  according to whether the action's effects result in a bene-
 fit or  a  cost to society, the State can compare, roughly, the benefits with the
 costs.

     The level of difficulty in the benefit-cost assessment process is dictated
 by the complexity of the effects and responses to  the program actions.   For
 example, when benefits  and  costs of an  action are  clearcut and have  values
 that are  comparatively small,  a  simple qualitative assessment is  in order.  In
 these  cases,  the assessment process merely describes the distribution  of bene-
 fits and costs—i.e., who in  society receives the benefits and  who bears  the
 costs—presents the  results,  and organizes them for the water quality deci-
 sion.   However,  if a qualitative  assessment reveals that  potential benefits and
 costs  are  substantial or not clearcut,  a  more detailed  and comprehensive  as-
 sessment is  in order, as  shown  by the  steps in Figure 1-3.   In these  cases,
the practitioner must measure, value, and  discount the benefits and costs and
judge  the sensitivity of the  results.   In  most  instances, staff resources and
existing  information  can  be combined  for an assessment.  In a few situations,


                                    1-8

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
                            Identify the change in
                              use designation for
                              the river segment
                           Obtain results of the use-
                            attainability assessment
                               for river segment
     Clearcut Case
 List benefits and costs and
  make a determination of
   the complexity of the
benefits and costs for change
      in river segment
  Determine as much
   as feasible about
    quantified and
nonquantifiable benefits
                                                              1
                              Determine as much
                               as feasible about
                                quantified and
                             nonquantifiable costs
                      Determine whether benefits bear a
                        reasonable relationship to costs
                                                                         Complex Case
                           Determine plausibility
                                 of results
                          Highlight distribution of
                             benefits and costs
                              Present results of
                           benefit cost assessment
    Figure 1-2.  Key steps in a benefit-cost  assessment.
                                  1-9

-------
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                             Identify the change in
                              use designation for
                               the river segment
                            Obtain results of the use-
                            attainability assessment
                               for river segment
                           List benefits and costs and
                            make a determination of
                             the complexity of the
                          benefits and costs for change
                                in river segment
Determine nonquantifiable,
  nonmonetized benefits
                                                 Complex Case
               Value quantifiable
            benefits using techniques
                  in Chapter 3
        Determine nonquantifiable,
            nonmonetized costs
 Value quantifiable
costs using techniques
     in Chapter 4
                           Translate benefits and cost
                           values into common units
                           using a discount rate and
                           appropriate time horizon
                          Conduct sensitivity analysis
                          for key variables and check
                              for less than fully
                              employed resources
                             Highlight distribution
                             of benefits and costs
                               Present results of
                            benefit-cost assessment
 Figure 1-3.   Key steps in a complex benefit-cost assessment.
                                    1-10

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
outside  assistance  may  be  needed  for a  more  detailed  assessment;  likely
candidates  include area  universities and consulting firms.   Regardless of out-
side assistance, following the flow chart can ensure good quality results.

     Thus,  the  strength of  benefit-cost assessment is its  ability to  organize
material  in a consistent  manner and  yet  remain  flexible enough to accommodate
a wide range of  cases.   Nonetheless,  the practitioner must recognize that each
program action will  introduce  hew complexities requiring judgments that can  be
made .based  only on an  understanding of the strengths and weaknesses of the
benefit-cost assessment process.

1.6  KEY CONSIDERATIONS IN AN ASSESSMENT

    . Four  practical problems  arise  in implementing general benefit-cost prin-
ciples:   determining  a  baseline, determining  the  primary  effects,  avoiding
double counting, and using expenditures  to measure benefits.

     The benefits and  costs  of  any water quality action  reflect  both  regula-
tions  already  in place  and  specific features  of the   affected  water  bodies.
This means  the  baseline  must be identified before the  benefits  and costs of a
hew action can be determined.   For example, technology-based requirements,
and  any variants of them,  usually  form  the regulatory baseline for additional
water  quality  decisions.  In  cases  where  the  technology-based  requirements
have  not been met,  determining the  baseline is difficult  due to  uncertainties
in the  predictions of  the effects  that the in-place regulations will produce.
Effective enforcement  is geherajly  assumed  for  existing  regulations.   In  an
actual  assessment, practitioners will have to make judgments about these base-
line  issues.   If  uncertainty exists  in the determination of the.baseline, this
should  be  clearly stated and addressed later,  when  the plausibility  of the
overall assessment is considered.

     The specific attributes of  a  site are  also important in linking  benefits
with the effects  of water quality decisions.   For example,  .swimming  benefits
will not  likely be significant for a river  that is only a  few feet  deep in places
and has  considerable  current, no complementary facilities  (such as beaches  or
access points), or large amounts of barge traffic.  However, swimming may  be
important when adjacent parks  and facilities are  present  and pollution  is the
limiting factor,  as is  the case for certain  river pools  in the Mississippi  River
in the Minneapolis  area  [Larson,  1981].  Similarly, the costs of  achieving  a
particular  level of water quality will  depend on site-specific water quality  as
it  existed  before  the  regulatory  action took effect.   The  analyses  of  use-
attainability  site-specific criteria, and wasteload allocation,  any one of which
may  be  performed as  an optional  part  of water  quality standards decisions,
can be a valuable source  of technical information.

     Another important distinction  is  between primary  and secondary  benefits
and costs.   Primary benefits  and  costs  arise  directly  from  the action,  while
secondary  benefits  and  costs follow  the impact  of the primary  ones.   Only
primary  benefits  and costs should be  included in an assessment, because link-
ages are often too imprecise to make  even  a  rough determination of secondary
benefits  and costs.   For example,  .while  increased recreation  activities and
                                      7-11

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
enhanced ecological  diversity are among  the  primary benefits of a water quality
improvement,  the  increased revenues  to  providers of  recreation equipment,
for example,  are simply expenditures—secondary benefits-- not primary bene-
fits.   When  these  expenditures  are  included,  the opportunities for double
.counting  increase substantially.  If increased  receipts of recreation equipment
suppliers are added to willingness to pay, then  that part of users' willingness
to pay is double  counted.  In effect, including secondary benefits in an  as-
sessment  opens up the assessment to the  same suspicions that plague some
applications of traditional cost-benefit analysis.

     The distinction, between  primary and  secondary benefits is  important in
the solution  of  another problem that arises  in  a benefit-cost assessment:   the
use of an expenditure approach to  measure  benefits.   The expenditure  ap-
proach adds  up an area's recreation-related expenditures.  This reflects  the
costs  of recreation, not an  individual's willingness  to pay  for recreation.   For
example,  the approach would  include  the  costs of the fishing gear  itself—
amounts that  are  costs and not benefits;   In  addition,   it  does not count  the
difference between  the maximum an  individual would pay  and  the amount  he
actually pays—in  technical  terms  the consumer  surplus.   In  effect,  the  ex-
penditure approach  includes some costs on the  benefits  side of  the ledger and
excludes other benefits entirely.

     Total recreation  expenditures  may be  useful  in identifying some of  the
effects on a community's  economic  activity  (e.g., increased sales tax receipts
or  recreation-related  employment).   Even in  this  limited  use, however,  the
use of  total  expenditures  omits important flows of funds out of the community
to pay for  goods  externally  produced.   Confusion on  these points often  re-
sults  because it seems  logical  that expenditures should be  benefits.  However,
expenditures  are  costs  and benefits;  they  are not al|  benefits.  Both double
counting and miscounting occur when this approach is used.

1.7  SUMMARY

     Benefit-cost assessment:

          Applies  a formal  dose of  common sense to   evaluating water
          quality regulations and programs.

          Provides  a  flexible  approach  for organizing the information
          needed to make water quality decisions.

          Enhances  but  does  not  supplant   the  value  judgments   of
          decisionmakers.

          Uses.society as the basis for accounting benefits and costs.

          Focuses  on  individual willingness  to  pay and  opportunity cost
          to measure benefits and costs, respectively.

          Concentrates  on  primary benefits and costs.
                                     1-12

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
1.8  GUIDE TO HANDBOOK

     This  handbook  is  organized into six chapters.  Chapter  1  is the  intro-
duction to benefit-cost  assessment.   Chapter 2  shows how to include intangi-
bles arid  distribution effects in  an  assessment  and considers the question of
discounting benefits  and costs.   Chapter 3 describes specific methods for esti-
mating the benefits of water quality programs,  including techniques for devel-
oping  the monetary  components  of  benefits needed in complex cases.  Chap-
ter 4 gives the  basics  of estimating costs, focusing on the  incremental  costs
of water  quality regulations.   Chapter 5 describes a  sensitivity  analysis as a
guide to  a plausible  assessment  and highlights  methods of presenting the re-
sults of an  assessment.  Chapter 6 illustrates  benefit-cost  assessment prac-
tices with simple,  moderately difficult, and complex causes to reflect  different
types of water quality decisions.
                                     1-13

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                                  CHAPTER  2

                   ISSUES IN A  BENEFIT-COST ASSESSMENT
 2.1   INTRODUCTION

      How  can  intangible  benefits  and  costs  be  included  in a  benefit-cost
 assessment?  What  does it mean  to discount benefits  and  costs?  Are there
 rules  of  thumb  for discounting?  Does benefit-cost  assessment  ignore  the
 distribution, of benefits and costs?

      In  practice, the positive  and  negative effects of  a  program action occur
 at different points  in time,  affecting  households and  firms  over a number of
 years.   In many  assessments the  need  or ability to monetize  benefits  and
 costs may be small, or limited resources may preclude monetizing.  Clearly, a
 need exists for  a  logical  approach  to intangibles  and for a  convenient way to
 include them in an assessment.

      For those assessments where benefits  and  costs  are monetized,  two main
 "adding  up"  issues arise:  discounting  and distribution.  Discounting  pro-
 vides a  consistent basis for adding benefits and costs over  time.  |t  is one of
 the  most complex and controversial  issues in an assessment.   Similarly, simply
 adding benefits and costs over people or firms may hide important issues.

     To  explain  how  a  benefit-cost  assessment  addresses  these  important
 Issues,   Section 2.2  discusses  intangible benefits and costs  and uses arrays,
 or tabular, displays, to feature  them  in  the  assessment. Section 2.3  briefly
 describes  how to measure  impacts  on firms and households,  and Section 2.4
 illustrates  how  the  distribution  of  benefits  and costs can  be included in  an
 assessment.   Section 2.5  describes  the discount rate, its role in  a benefit-
 cost assessment  and key  issues  in selecting a discount rate.  Finally,  Sec-
 tion  2.6  summarizes the  chapter's major points.

 2.2  INCLUDING INTANGIBLES IN A BENEFIT-COST ASSESSMENT

     Introduction

     The uses prescribed  in the Clean Water Act for the water quality stand-
ards  are  likely  to   provide  intangible  benefits  relating  to  enhanced species
diversity and ecological  habitats  and  improved  aesthetics.  By its  incommen-
surability,  this  type of  benefit  presents  problems for  determining the  net
benefits  of a  use designated under the standards  program--or for any water
quality program.  The types of benefits or costs that comprise the intangibles
group  change over time  with  improvements  in  valuation  techniques.   For
example, the  travel  cost technique  estimates willingness  to pay for recreation
benefits  that  initially were treated  as  intangibles.  This section  provides a
                                      2-1

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
 method for including intangibles  in  a  benefit-cost assessment.  Volume II will
 contain more details on intangible benefits.

      A recommended  method uses  a  system of tabular displays, or arrays,  to
 present both  tangible and intangible  benefits.  These arrays are  tailored  to
 fit the  nature of the  assessment being  conducted.   The  first  array  simply
 lists  and  describes  the benefits  and  costs.  A  second array  presents mone-
 tized values only for those benefits  and costs for which monetization is almost
 always  accepted,  with  the  remaining  benefits  and  costs  being  listed,  de-
 scribed,  and  quantified to the  extent possible.   These  values are based on
 individuals' willingness  to  pay and opportunity cost as measured by the tech-
 niques  presented  in Chapters 3  and  4.   The  final  array  presents as many
 benefits and  costs in monetized terms  as possible,  with the  other  benefits and
 costs being listed, described,  and quantified.

 Example

      Suppose  a  State is  considering  adding  the  fish and  wildlife use to a
 stream  that is currently designated  for  agricultural and industrial uses.  A
 system  of arrays for a benefit-cost assessment of this change  in use designa-
 tion is illustrated in Tables 2-1,  2-2,  and 2-3.

      The first array  (see  Table 2-1) lists and describes  all the benefits  and
 costs  in  qualitative  terms.   In  cases where  issues are clearcut,  this array
 would,  by  itself,  provide  information  sufficient  for making  the decision.   As
 issues  become more  complex,  additional arrays  are essential  for  information
 sufficient to make the decision.

      The second array  for  this  example  (see  Table 2-2)  presents monetary
 values for  benefits and costs for  only those  categories that almost all  practi-
 tioners  agree can  be monetized.   This  supplemental  information in the second
 array clarifies  the  issues  in the  assessment by  focusing attention  on  the
 nonmonetized  values.  This  array shows that the  low end on the range of
 monetized recreation  benefits is  exceeded by the  high end on the range of the
 costs and  that the action  produces nonmonetized benefits.  The decisionmaker
 would have to determine how the  nonmonetized aesthetic benefits  and ecologi-
 cal diversity  influence the net result given  the overlap in the  range estimated
 for benefits and costs.
                      i
     The system  of  arrays shows how a  benefit-cost assessment  can  reduce
 the dimensions  of a  complex  issue to  focus  the  decisionmaker's  attention on
the most difficult  aspects.   The  last array (see Table 2-3) shows  the mone-
tization of  as  many  benefits  and  costs as  possible.  The range  of monetized
 benefits  is  estimated  to be $17 million  to $37  million, with additional nonmone-
tized  benefits attributable  to the  enhancement  of  the ecological  diversity.
The estimated  costs  of attaining  the additional use  designated range between
$9 million and $14 million.

     Several  features  of  this  example  call  for  additional   discussion.   The
estimated monetary values  for aesthetic benefits  move the benefit  range to a
level  at  which benefits exceed both the minimum and maximum estimates  of the
                                    2-2

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
               Table 2-1.  Benefits and Costs of Attaining  Fish
                          and Wildlife Use:  Array 1
Description of Benefits

   1.  Provide an additional resource that can support  swimming, fishing,  and
       recreation  near water in  a metropolitan area with only limited  substitutes
       available.

   2.  Improve the  aesthetic value  for users of  the  resources services,  such
       as recreators or property owners near  the stream.

   3.  Improve the  aesthetic vatue for residents  of the area based  on  possible
       use in future or just from knowing the  stream is cleaner.

   4.  Enhance the ecological  diversity  of the  stream area  by  providing an
       improved  habitat for fish species  and wildlife from  surrounding areas.
       However, none of these species  is unique or endangered.

Description of Costs

   1.  The residents  of  the  city will  require  advanced  treatment for their
       wastes.

   2.  Three  industrial  dischargers will  have to  modify their waste treatment
       operations.
               Table 2-2.  Benefits  and Costs of Attaining  Fish
                          and Wildlife Use:  Array  2
                                          Quantity
                        Monetary value
                         (million $,
                       present values)
Types of Benefits

   1.  Fishing, swimming,  recreation
       near water

   2.  Improved aesthetics for
       users--recreators and prop-
       erty owners near stream

   3.  Improved aesthetics for
       nonusers--vatue  to residents
       in area from  knowing  stream
       is clean should they use it
       or from just  knowing it is
       clean

   4.  Enhanced ecological  diversity
1 million visits
10 to 30
Types of Costs

   1.   Advanced treatment for
       municipal wastes

   2.   Advanced treatment for
       industrial dischargers
10 new  fish species,
smallmouth bass and
others;  1,000 acres
of improved wildlife
habitat;  no unique
species  are provided
1 new  plant


3 additional treat-
ment operations
8 to 10
1 to 4
                                  2-3

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
               Table 2-3.  Benefits and Costs of Attaining Fish
                          and Wildlife Use:  Array 3
                                           Quantity
                        Monetary value
                         (million  $,
                       present values)
Types of Benefits
   1.  Fishing, swimming,  recreation
       near water

   2.  Improved aesthetics for
       users--recreators and prop-
       erty owners near stream

   3.  Improved aesthetics for
       nonusers

   4.  Enhanced ecological  diversity
1 million visits
10 to 30


5
Types of Costs

   1.  Advanced treatment for
       municipal wastes

   2.  Advanced treatment cost
       for industrial dischargers
10 new  fish species,     Not monetized
although no unique
species  are provided;
1,000 acres of improved
wildlife  habitat.
1 new  plant             8 to 10
3 additional treat-       1  to 4
ment operations
costs.    By  monetizing  these  benefits  with  a  contingent  valuation  survey
(discussed in Chapter 3),  the  practitioner can show that the minimum benefits
exceed  even the highest cost.  This makes a strong case for adding the use.
In addition,  the array  in Table  2-3  shows  nonmonetized benefits  that would
increase the total  value of the benefits even  more.   This example  illustrates
the case for a  river  segment with large recreation  potential that justifies the
extra cost involved in carrying out the detailed assessment.   River segments
that have  intermittent flows or whose entire flow  is  effluent would  have low
recreation potential and would not  require such a detailed assessment.

     To  show  how the system of arrays can  present assessment results, the
discussion  of this  example concentrates on the efficiency  aspects  of the use
designation.   As  noted  in Section 2.4, however,  the  decision  process .also
should consider information on distribution effects.
                                    2-4

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
2.3  COST  IMPACT MEASURES

     This  section  describes the general approach and some specific measures
for assessing the  cost impacts on communities and industries of meeting water
quality  regulations.  This  handbook  does  not advocate  the  use of any one
measure;  rather,   it  emphasizes  that  impacts  be  evaluated.   Overall,  the
objective is to  determine the incremental  effect of compliance costs on earn-
ings,  production,  and  employment in  the affected  locality.   However,  the
financial  ability  of a  community  or  industry  to absorb  these  costs  is  also
important.

     For each major impact category,  the following  sections describe one or
more   measures  with  varying degrees of  sophistication,  data  requirements,
estimation  methods, feasibility,  and accuracy.  By no means :are these meth-
ods the.only way to proceed.

Assessing  Household Impacts

     The share of  publicly owned  treatment works (POTW) costs allocated to
households  in the  form  of higher sewer  or  water charges is assumed to be
borne  directly by those  households,  reducing annual income by the amount of
the  total annual  costs.   This implies that households  cannot pass  oh these
costs  by increasing their wages.  Together  with data on household income,
total  costs  of compliance and  community  indebtedness  are used  to develop
measures of the  ability  of households to  bear  these costs—i.e.,   how these
costs  affect income arid  indebtedness.  The discussion  of impact measures is
kept brief here  because an EPA document, the.Financial Capability Gu|debook,*
provides a detailed guide to community  financial capability  analysis.

     Household  impact measures are divided into two major types:  ability to
pay  and  ability  to finance.   Ability-to-pay measures focus on the ability of
the residents to bear the costs of water quality improvements,  regardless of
the  current financial status  of the community.   Ability-to-finance  measures
focus  on  the  ability of the community  to finance the costs  of compliance.  The
Financial Capability Guidebook develops  11  key  indicators used  to  judge the
ability to bear the impacts specified by these measures.

     Ability to Pay

     The measure  of ability to pay  is the  ratio of compliance costs to median
household  income.  Compliance costs  are  defined  as total  annual costs:  the
sum  of annualized capital costs,  operation  and  maintenance costs, and  contri-
butions  to  contingency  funds.  Focusing on values for the median  household
is convenient, but  particular  situations  may call  for  a more detailed examina-
tion of the distribution of income or wealth in the community.
     *Municipal  Finance  Officers  Association  and Peat,  Marwick, Mitchell  &
Co.,  Financial Capability Guidebook  (Draft),  prepared  for  EPA,  Office of
Water Program Operations,  Washington, D.C., May  1982.   Contact the  OWpO
at EPA for further information about this document.
                                      2-5

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     The Income measure may  be used to estimate two kinds  of cost impacts:
 the  incremental costs of a  particular water quality program and the total costs
 of compliance associated with all treatment.   In some  cases, total costs may be
 useful because  the practitioner is interested  in a view of cost impacts  overall.
 For  specific water programs,  however,  a focus on  the incremental costs of
 decisions .that  move water  quality  beyond that resulting  from the  statutory,
 technology-based  controls  can   reveal the  cost  impacts  due  to the  individual
 program.

     Financial Capability

     The financial  capability of a community has  a  significant effect on  its
 ability to raise additional funds in the bond  market.  If a community has high
 indebtedness or low tax revenues,  it will have  a. lower bond rating and face
 higher costs of capital.  The impact measure is the  total  outstanding  debt of
 the community before and after  the project being considered.

 Assessing  Industrial Impacts

     A firm's compliance cost may  arise  either from  direct costs  of  treatment
 facilities or process changes or from its  share of POTW costs.  In  turn,  these
 costs lead to changes  in profitability, output, and employment and may  result
 in partial  or complete  closures.  Of  course, an  accurate  measure  of impact
 requires  some  estimate  of  a  business  cash flow, but  this  estimate  may  be
 difficult  to obtain unless the companies  concerned cooperate.  Thus,  a  large
 tradeoff  exists  among  the  measures .with  respect to  feasibility and  accuracy.
 Table 2-4 summarizes the proposed  impact measures,  data sources,  and  their
 availability  and reliability.  The measures will be described  in greater  detail
 in Volume II.

 Assessing Changes in Employment,  Output, and Prices

     Changes in output and employment  in  response to treatment  costs  are
 important because  they  give rise to indirect impacts.  If workers are unem-
 ployed, they reduce their spending; if a  plant reduces output, its demand for
 inputs from supplying  firms slackens, with indirect repercussions  on commun-
 ity income and  employment.  Even  if estimating  indirect impacts is infeasible,
the direct effects  of compliance costs on community employment and income are
 useful  for assessing the equity implications of a  regulatory  action--"who is
affected?1'

     As  a  rule  of  thumb for assessing the effect  of  regulatory actions,  firms
usually  cannot  pass through  treatment  costs  by  raising prices.    This rule
normally   holds  for  water   quality standard  actions  because  they  are  site-
specific  and may  affect  only certain businesses.  Although  the rule may  not
hold  for  some regulatory actions, it is difficult to predict  under what  circum-
stances firms might be able to pass through costs.
                                   2-6

-------
1
1
1








1













1

1

1









1
1
IB

Table 2-4. Summary of Industrial Impact Measures


Measure


Profitability
(including closure)

1. Cost/sales ratio


2. Cost/production
cost ratio
3. Net cash flow


4. Rate of return


5. Net present value


6. Company solvency

Reductions in employment
and output
1 . Due to closure
2. Due to output
reduction
Price changes expected
to be small




Source





Production and
price estimates
or public data
bases
EPA economic
impact analysis
Plant financial
data

Plant and company
financial data

Plant and company
financial data

Company financial
data •


Plant data
Plant data, engi-
neering report





Availa- Relia-
bility bility





High Low

/
High Low

Medium Medium


Low High


Low High


Depends Depends
on size on size


Medium Medium
Medium Medium





2.4 WHAT TO DO ABOUT DISTRIBUTION: PROBLEMS IN
ADDING UP OVER PEOPLE
I ntroduction







A net benefits estimate does not evaluate projects based oh the distri-
bution of net benefits. Rather,


the evaluation is based on efficiency criteria,

U.S.

EPA Headquarters Library
Mail code 3201
2-7 120° Pennsy/vanfa Avenue NW
Washington DC 20460




-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 which  show how  to  allocate  society's  resources  to maximize  well-being.*
 Although  the weights  assigned  to  individual  recipients  of the  benefits and
 costs  of  a project  are treated  equally, the distribution of net benefits can  be
 described for  the  'policy under evaluation.   In these descriptions, benefits
 and  costs  are  separated  according to  the economic agents  affected.   For
 example,  one might classify households  by income  group, or firms  by  indus-
 try,  and  evaluate  each  group's share of the net  benefits.  Then, the overall
 benefit-cost assessment can account for distribution.

      Some attempts have  been made to  explicitly  include  equity  (in terms of
 the effects  of the  project on  different income  groups) in  benefit-cost assess-
 ment.  They are not  uniformly accepted.   All  of  the weighting  schemes  are
 based on  the premise that  the extra utility  or satisfaction derived from  an
 extra  dollar of  income  declines as income increases.  Thus,  redistribution  of
 income will lead to increases in total utility or satisfaction for society.

     There  are  flaws  inherent in any  weighting  scheme for benefit-cost  as-
 sessment.  The  most difficult  one to overcome is that it is hard to get society
 to  agree  on the appropriate  weights.   Equity in income is only one possibil-
 ity; regional and racial  equity are others.  In the final analysis, the weights
 are simply  attempts to  "guesstimate"  the decisionmaker's preferences.  This
 does  not  imply  that distribution information should not be developed.  Rather,
 it  suggests  that the tradeoff  between efficiency (as measured  by the aggre-
 gate  net  benefits)  and  various types of equity considerations (as reflected in
 the distributions of these net  benefits  among economic agents .under  different
 classifications)  is  unlikely  to  be  capable  of being assigned a  fixed  relation-
 ship.  Ultimately,  the importance of distributional issues will depend on the
 decisionmaker's judgment,

    ' Two examples  can  be used to illustrate how distributional  information has
 supplemented the  conventional net  benefit  information in a benefit-cost as-
 sessment.

 Example  I                                    .

     Suppose an:improvement in water quality will  provide. $10 million a year in
 net benefits.  The  distribution issue  is  to determine who will receive  these
 benefits.   The  most commonly  used method is to array  the benefits by the
 shares that will  accrue to different income groups, as  shown below:
            Income  ($)

            Less than 10,000
            10,000 to 20,000
            20,000 to 35,000
            More than 35,000
Percent of net benefits

         20
         30
         35
         15
     *Efficiency  criteria  indicate both the  cheapest way of achieving a partic-
ular level of  water quality  and what level of water quality  makes sense given
competing uses of resources.

-------
r



 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I

 I
     This  change would favor lower income groups:   half of the net benefits
 accrue to  people  with  incomes  of $20,000  or less,  and  over three-fourths
 accrue to people with  incomes of less than $35,000 a year.  By quantifying
 and monetizing benefits and  costs,  benefit-cost assessment provides a clear
 picture  of the distribution effects of the  change.  The distribution of any
 intangible benefits and costs also should be considered in the decision.

 Example II

     Consider the same situation as in the previous  example with  $10 million
 in  net  benefits  from  the  change  in  water  quality.  Table 2-5 arrays  the
 distribution  of  benefits and of project  costs.  Rather than  arraying by  income
 groups, the  categories  in Table 2-5  break down the distribution of benefits
 and costs  over broad  groups in society  to  illustrate another  way that  distri-
 bution effects can be highlighted.


                Table 2-5.  Distribution of Benefits and Costs

 Benefits:  Who Receives?

       Users of river for recreation

       People who receive enhanced aesthetics values for river

       Downstream users for municipal water supplies

       Downstream companies who use water for industrial  processes

 Costs:  Who  Bears?

       Residents who incur higher sewer  and water bills because of advanced
       treatment requirements for wastes

       Stockholders of companies who have to install new  equipment or change
       production processes to meet the standards

       Consumers who purchase  products whose prices are increased  as a  re-
       sult of companies' compliance
Summary:  Distribution

     Information on distribution effects of water quality programs is an essen-
tial ingredient in  a benefit-cost assessment.   It can  be described with either
summary  measures  like  income group shares,  or simply listed  in  narrative
form.
                                      2-9

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
2.5  DISCOUNTING FUTURE BENEFITS AND COSTS:  ADDING UP
     OVER TIME

     One of  the most crucial issues in  a benefit-cost  assessment that relies on
monetized  benefits  and  costs is  the  selection  of the appropriate  discount
rate—an  interest rate used to translate  dollar amounts of benefits and costs
occurring in different years into  a common  unit of comparison, usually a pres-
ent  value.  The discount rate is  a positive number because individuals prefer
immediate consumption  and the associated immediate satisfaction to  future con-
sumption  and the corresponding  future satisfaction.  Then, to persuade indi-
viduals to give up immediate consumption in exchange for  future consumption,
the  level of  consumption must be increased at that later date. This increase
is an opportunity cost and  is .demonstrated, for example,  when companies pay
interest,  or  share future profits,  to take advantage of  current investment op-
portunities.   Preference for  satisfaction  now rather  than later—technically
known as the  positive rate  of time  preference—is  demonstrated when someone
installs new  carpet  on a time  payment plan or finances  a new car.  The  satis-
faction  or utility from  the  carpet or car  is gained  now at the expense of a
financing charge.

     There are five key concepts in determining discount rates:

          Social  rate  of  time  preference:   the rate  at  which society is
          willing to exchange  present  consumption for  future consump-
          tion.

          Consumption  rate  of  interest:   the  rate at  which  individuals
          are willing  to  exchange present  consumption for future con-
          sumption.

          Marginal  rate of return  on  private investment:  the incremental
          return on the last unit of investment  by  a  private firm.

          Opportunity  cost of public investment:   the cost of a govern-
          ment investment measured in  terms of forgone  private consump-
          tion or investment.

          Risk:   the degree to which  investment  in a public project will
          affect the variation in the outcome of  all  public investment.

     While a  large  share of  the  costs of  meeting a water quality  standard
occurs in years  immediately  after  a standard is .set (e.g.,  firms invest in new
treatment processes,  and cities  construct advance waste  treatment  plants),
benefits  will  not accrue until after the  new plants and processes are  in place.
These  benefits  may accrue  for 50 or  100  years—a period over which dollar
amounts  of  both benefits and  costs  will vary greatly.  The  pattern  of dis-
counted  net  benefits often  will look very different if a high discount rate  is
used rather  than a  low one.  As  this example shows,  assessing benefits and
costs of  any water  quality  program   requires an appreciation of the  basic
principles underlying  the definition and  the selection of  an  appropriate dis-
count rate,  an understanding  of the empirical  implications  of discounting, and
a practical knowledge of how  to work with discounting techniques.


                                     2-10

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Time  Preference:   What Is It?*

     The use of discount rates in benefit-cost assessment  can  be explained  by
viewing  discounting  issues within the context of an ideal market economy, the
characteristics  of  which  include perfect competition in all  markets, complete
certainty in decisions.,  no transaction costs,  no taxes, and no  limitations  on
any credit  market.  In  such an  economy,  all  goods are priced  at  the  oppor-
tunity costs of  the  inputs used to  produce them,  and individuals  and busi-
nesses are  able to borrow or lend,  subject to their ability to repay, as much
as  they  desire at the  market rate  of  interest, which  is determined  by the
demand and supply of loanable funds.       .

     In  hopes  of  obtaining  future  earnings,  businesses  in this ideal world
would  invest funds to. the point where their extra benefit equals their  oppor^
tunity cost.  In this  economy, the  market interest  rate will be  the opportun-
ity cost of capital for  the firm.   Consequently, optimizing behavior by each
business and  efficiently  working markets  will  ensure that the market interest
rate will be equal  to the marginal  return on  investment.   The  firm could not
rearrange  its  investments and  improve its long-term  profit picture.   At the
same  time,  individuals would arrange their consumption and savings such that
their own  marginal rate  of time preference (also  known  as the consumption
rate of interest) would equal  the market  rate of interest.  In this  ideal case,
the  final outcome  is that  market forces  create  an equilibrium in which  an
individual's  consumption  rate  of interest and  a  firm's  marginal  return  on
investment  are  the same  because both correspond to the market rate of inter-
est.  This  equilibrium ensures  an  efficient allocation of resources  over time.
If these equalities  were  not maintained  (for example,  if the  consumption rate
of  interest  were less than the marginal return  on investment),  an  individual
could improve  his  welfare (by consuming  less,  saving,  and earning  a  return
that permitted greater consumption in the future).

     Introducing public investments—such  as those mandated by water  quality
programs—requires that  the resources supporting them displace  either  private
consumption or private  investment.   An efficient allocation of resources means
that these investments earn a  return at least equal to  the marginal return  on
capital or  the consumption  rate  of  interest that would be required for these
alternative  uses (i.e.,  private  investments or  consumption).   If  it  is also
assumed  that all individuals are alike with respect to factors determining their
rates of  time preference,  society's overall  rate of time preference should equal
the market rate.

     The implication  for  selecting a  discount  rate  for  the water quality pro-
grams  in an ideal  society is that either the  social rate of time  preference or
the opportunity cost of  capital  would  be appropriate  because  they are  the
same—i.e.,  both  are  equal  to  the  market rate of interest.   Unfortunately,
when  the assumptions of the ideal  case are relaxed, the two rates diverge.
These  divergences explain  why the selection of a discount  rate  for  public
sector investments  has been such  a difficult and often controversial issue.
    This section draws extensively oh Lind et al. [1982]
                                     2-11

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
How To Determine  the  Djscount Rate in a  Less  Than Ideal World

     The  selection of a discount rate for a benefit-cost assessment of a water
quality program must  be  accomplished in a world considerably different from
that of the ideal  economy.  Some of the most  important  divergences  from the
ideal economy can be attributed to the following  factors:

          The tax on  corporate income,  which drives a wedge  between
          the private rate of return and  the rate of time preference.  A
          higher rate of return on  private investment is  required to  off-
          set the  effects of  income taxes, which  cause  the  divergence
          between  social and private rates.

          The dependence of  future generations on  decisions  made  by
          present  generations.  This dependence gives rise to a "public
          good"--the welfare of the future generations—that may not be
          included in the decisions of the private market.

          Private  markets,  which  may  be  out of  long-run  equilibrium
          with an  immediate discount  rate  different  from the appropriate
          long-term rate.

          The  determination  of the  appropriate  private market  rate,
          which  is difficult because there  are  numerous  capital markets,
          each with its own interest rate.

     »    Public investment  dollars,  which  do not  necessarily  displace
          private investment dollars but  may  instead  use tax  revenues
          that displace current consumption in the private  markets.

     Attempts to reconcile these divergences  have created a complex literature
on  the criteria  for selecting  an appropriate discount  rate for public invest-
ments  or  regulatory evaluations under  different  circumstances.   Lind [1982]
has distilled  this  literature,  concluding  that  the rationale for discount rate
selection should be based on the full  opportunity costs of capital.

     Lind's  approach does  not ignore the potential divergence between  socie-
ty's social  rate of time preference and  the market rate  of interest.   Rather,
he  suggests that the social rate of discount be set equal to the  social  rate of
time preference and that the shadow price  of capital be used  to adjust for the
full opportunity costs  of capital.  The  shadow price of  capital is  defined  as
the present value of the future stream of consumption benefits associated with
$1 of private investment discounted at the social rate of time preference.

     A  benefit-cost  assessment  to  evaluate  government  investment  decisions
based  on  this approach considers the implications that  investments  have for
consumption over  time.  The basic question to  be answered  is, "What does
public investment  displace?"  To the extent public investment  displaces pri-
vate  investment,  that  portion of the costs  of the public project should  be
valued at the shadow price of capital.  That  is, the  costs of  this portion  of
the investment  are valued  in  terms of the  consumption  forgone.  When  the
                                    2-12

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
forgone  consumption due to displaced investment is added  to  the balance of
the costs (i.e.,  those displacing  immediate  consumption),  all costs have been
converted to  their equivalent losses  in  private consumption.  Similarly, bene-
fits  that lead to  increased private  investment  should also  be  adjusted  to
reflect their potential to yield  future  consumption streams.   The adjustment is
to multiply  that  share of the private  investment  by the shadow price of capi-
tal.   This  procedure adjusts  benefits  and costs at each  point in time and
expresses them  in  terms of the equivalent  amount of .consumption that  could
be obtained.

     Table 2-6 .shows estimates of various  parameters  so that  a  practitioner
could use this general procedure in a benefit-cost assessment.   The estimated
value for the marginal  return on  private investment in Table 2-6 is  10 per-
cent.  This approximation is based on judgment and the empirical  relationship
that the estimated average  return, adjusted for  inflation,  is between 10 and
15 percent.   More  accurate  measurements of the  costs of capital are hindered
by  the Inconsistency between accounting data and  economic concepts,  and by
implicit  adjustments both for risk in the  returns  to capital data and for firms'
inconsistencies in  following  established  procedures to make capital budgeting
decisions.

     Based  on depreciable assets data for 1973,  1974, and 1975, the length of
the typical  private  investment  is estimated at 15 years,  with a range of 10 to
20 years.  Based on empirical  work on consumption and  savings, the  marginal
propensity to  save is assumed to be 0.2.
         Table 2-6.   Summary of Final Description  Factors  Influencing
                           Shadow Price of Capital
Shadow
price of
capital
1.62 to
2.57a
1.9b
Marginal
propensity
to save
0.2
0.2
Marginal
return .on
private capital
(%)
10
10 to 15
Social rate
of time
preference
(%)
2
2 to 6
Length of typical
private investment
(years)
10 to 20
15
 This row is  based on Lind's  Table 4 comparing the  shadow  price of capital
 under a  range of assumptions  for the social  rate of time preference,  marginal
 return on private investment, and length of typical private investment.

 This row is  based  oh  Lind's discussion on  pp.  101-102 of the unpublished
 manuscript.    The  returns  on  private  capital  are  pre-tax  returns.   The
 shadow  price  of 1.9  is the central  value  associated  with  the  variations  in
 each of  the parameters involved.  The range of  values was 1.65 to 2.15.
 The  range of  social  rates of  time preference  are  reported to indicate  that
 they would be  consistent with this shadow price.
                                     2-13

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
      In the  procedure, the  social  rate  of  time  preference is  set  equal  to the
consumption  rate  of  interest  for individuals.   Unfortunately,  there  is  no
unique rate of interest in the  real economy.   But it is  possible  to gain some
insight  into  individuals'  rates  of time  preference  from their  savings  and
investment  decisions.  For example,  the real  after-tax average rate of  return
on  treasury bills (a safe investment available to many people)  over the  period
1926  to 1978 was -0.5 percent for an individual  in the 20-percent  tax bracket,
and the  return  on a mutual fund containing  "average market" stocks totaled
4,6 percent.   For  individuals,  the  real  rate of  return must lie  somewhere
between the riskless treasury bill rate and the  stock market equity  returns. ,

      Adjusting  for  the effects  of  unanticipated  inflation  shows that the mar-
ginal  rate of time  preference must be  in the range of -2 and  5 percent, with
the average close to 0.   Regardless of the actual  point estimate  selected,  it
will be considerably different from the 10 percent real rate of discount recom-
mended by the Office  of  Management and Budget (OMB)  for public, investment
projects.*

      The shadow price  of capital can be calculated from the  estimates  of the
other  parameters  following  Lind's  procedures.   Specifically,  Lind  estimates
that  the  most likely value is within the range  between  1.65  and  2.15.  This
shadow price  is then  used  as  described  above to convert  the  benefits and
costs into consumption equivalents.

Including Risk in an Assessment of Discount Rates

     So  far  the implications  of uncertainty for  determining the discount rate
have  been  implicitly ignored.   Since  the  levels of  benefits  and costs are
uncertain, there should  be adjustments for the  probabilities that a particular
level  of each  will  occur.  Depending on its  source  and nature,  the uncer-
tainty can either be addressed  in this choice  of a discount rate or be directly
reflected  in  the  measurement of benefits and  costs.   Alternatively, some com-
bination can  be attempted.  Each of these alternatives  will  be considered in
Volume II.

     The  main conclusion that can be drawn  from the risk studies covered in
Volume II is that the characteristics of the public investment project, together
with  the  relation  between  the variability  in the  public investment  and the
variability in  national  income,  are crucial  factors  in determining  whether a
riskless  or risk-adjusted discount  rate  should  be  used  in an assessment of
public  investments.   The important  relationship  that   must  be  explored  is
whether water quality  program  investments increase the  variability in national
income.   For  most  of these applications, the effects of risk will be small, and
a riskless rate can be used.
     *lt is  difficult to interpret this  rate  as  an estimate of the social rate of
time preference.   It may well  be the equivalent to a recommendation that all
projects be discounted at the  marginal  rate of  return on private investment.
Additional confusion is added by the Water Resources  Council [1979] guidelines
which  tie the discount rate to an  index.   The  current rate in this procedure
is 7-7/8 percent.


                                    2-14

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
What Are the Empirical  Implications  of the Discount Rate .Issues?*

     One of the  reasons for the controversy  concerning the use of discount
rates  is that the empirical  implications  of the discount rate can have  a sub-
stantial  influence  on  the outcome  of  the benefit-cost assessment.   Fox  and
Herfindahl  [1964]  reevaluated  Federal  water projects,  previously  evaluated  at
a  2-5/8  percent discount rate, at new  discount  rates of 4, 6, and 8 percent.
Nine percent of the projects that previously had benefits exceeding costs  at
2-5/8  percent  experienced the opposite result with a 4-percent discount rate;
64 percent  experienced  the  opposite  result  at a 6-percent rate;  and 80 per-
cent experienced the  opposite  result at  an  8-percent rate.   The implications
are  quite  clear:   Most  of the projects .had  costs exceeding benefits  at the
higher discount rate,  and  all had  positive  benefits  at the low 2r5/8 percent
rate.

     Many water  program regulations  or  projects will have  benefits that will
accrue 10,  20, 30, or  even 100 years in the  future and costs that could be
substantial  during initial periods.   For example,   suppose  a  water  quality
project requires a $1 million investment in 1982 and  will  provide $50 million  in
recreation  .benefits  at  the end of 50 years.   The net present  values at differ-
ent discount rates would  be as follows:
               Discount rate

                 5 percent
                 8 percent
                12 percent
Net present value

    3,336^186
        6,606
     -826,990
As  shown,  the discount rate is  crucial in  determining the ultimate assessment
of  benefits  and  costs.   This emphasizes  the  importance of  the sensitivity
analysis recommended in Chapter 5,  which  shows that in some cases there will
be  positive  net benefits regardless of the discount rate, while in others the
outcome of the assessment is very sensitive to the discount rate applied.

     Another important empirical distinction in discounting  is  the difference
between real and  nominal rates  of discount.   The difference is the expected
rate of inflation.   Most  benefit-cost analyses  are  conducted  using constant
dollar  values  for  the  benefits  and costs.   In these  cases  'the  real rate  of
discount should be used.

     Benefit-cost  assessments have employed real  discount rates ranging from
0 to 4 percent,  while the  nominal rates have  ranged  from  8 to 16 percent.
The higher  end  of  the scale for  nominal  rates  represents  the  influence  of
recent  high  levels of  inflation  and  market  interest  rates.   The .difference
between the real and  nominal rates is quite  substantial and indicates  why it is
important not to mix the two in  a  benefit-cost assessment. For  example, com-
pare the  implications  of  a real discount  rate of 2 percent and  a  nominal rate
of 10 percent  (inflation is expected to be approximately 8 percent).  With the
     *This discussion  is adapted from Just,  Hueth, and Schmitz [1982].
                                     3-15

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 nominal  rate  used as the discount  rate, society would  be indifferent between
 $1  now  and  $13,780  in  100 years.   However,  if a real rate is  employed, the
 difference  would be  $1  now versus  $7.24 in 100 years.  Thus, although  it
 seems low, given the high  interest the  economy is currently experiencing, a
 real discount rate of  2 to 4 percent may make  considerable sense in  a benefit-
 cost assessment where the long-term perspective is essential.

 The Simple Mechanics of Discounting

     This section offers a  brief review of the mechanics  of discounting.   The
 reader is urged  to consult a  finance text for present  value  tables  and  more
 detailed  discussions on discounting.

     The discounting problem  in  a  benefit-cost assessment is  how to translate
 benefits  and costs  occurring .in  different  periods  into  a common   basis for
 comparison.  The most  frequently  used  basis is  present value,   which  is
 defined  as  the  amount of money at the  present  time  that some  future amount
 is worth.  Discounting  is  the  process  of computing  the present value  of a
 future stream of dollars.*

     Consider a simple example that might arise in the assessment of a water
 quality  standards program.   Suppose  a State  is  considering  changing the
 presently unattained  use designation  for a river segment  from "fish  and  wild-
 life  propagation"  to "limited warmwater fishery."  In this case, there will  be a
 loss in  potential  benefits,  as well as cost savings from the  forgone pollution
 control  investment  for  cities  or industries.  The monetary values  for the
 benefits  and costs associated with this decision are as follows:

               Year         Benefits forgone      Cost savings

               1982              40,000             $100,000
               1983              40,000                10,000
               1984              40,000                10,000


 The discounting problem  is:

     1.   Select the appropriate discount rate.

     2.   Translate future  benefits  and  costs into  present  values for
          comparison.

     The discounting formula for this procedure is:

                                        1
                              P.V. =
                                     (HO*
     *For  simplicity,  assume  all dollars accrue  at  the end  of  each year  so
there is no need to account for differences within a year.
                                     2-16

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
 where

  P.V. = the present value factor for either benefits or costs

      i = the discount rate

      t = the time period.

 The  discount  factor  P.V.  is multiplied  by  the benefits or  costs  foK each
 period  in  the planning horizon; then  the  results are summed.   Suppose that
 i = 4 percent  with  the monetary values for  benefits and costs from  above.
 The discounting  calculations are the following:
(1982)
(t=0)
an nnn ±
(1983)
(t=1)
(1984)
(t=2)
     Benefits forgone  =  40,000 +


          Cost savings = 100,000 +


     Benefits forgone  =  40,000 + 38,462   +  36,982

          Cost savings— 100,000 +  9,615  +   9,246

      Net cost savings =  $3,317 .
$115,444

$118,861
The change  of the use  designation will yield a small positive cost savings.  In
this example,  the forgone  benefits  end  in 1984.   In  most cases, they  would
continue into the future for whatever time horizon is selected for the assess-
ment.
                                               i

     If the  benefit (or  cost)  stream is  constant  each year at A  for  the full
life of the project (assumed to be n  years),  the formula for the present value
can  be  rewritten  as  follows,  often  referred to  as the  present value  of  an
annuity:
                                            1
                              P = A
                                     1." (1+0
                                              n
where
     P = present value

     A = annual amount

     i = discount rate.

Present value  may  also  be determined  by  using  the tables in a  finance  or
accounting text.   Another .variation on the  discounting mechanics  is to trans-
                                    2-17

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
 late amounts into  annual  values that can be  compared.  The formula for this
 calculation,  often  referred to  as  the uniform-series  capital  recovery factor,
 is:
                                      i(l-H)
                              A  =  Pj
 Discounting:   A Summary Review

      While  the arguments  summarized  above  require  the  use of judgment  for
 each new situation, general guidelines do exist.  For a  wide range of water
 quality programs, the social rate of time preference  would range from 2 per-
 cent to a maximum of 6 percent.  The recommended procedure is to consider
 the implications  of each of these values for the discounted net benefits of  the
 decision.*  If the  present  value of net  benefits  is  positive and the  project
 decision  remains  unchanged, it is unnecessary to further  consider the techni-
 cal  issues  affecting the selection of one value  in  this range.   However,  for
 those cases where the value of net benefits  (i.e., positive versus negative) is
 affected  by the  discount  rate,  a more refined selection  is recommended that
 considers the practical implications  of  Lind's  analysis.  This  process requires
 answering four key questions:

      1.   What are the sources of the public investment  resources?  Are
          they tax  revenues  that   can,  in  principle,, displace private
          consumption  or investment?!   In addition,  what are the likely
          portions coming from  each source?  Answers to  these questions
          will  affect  the importance  of estimating  the shadow  price of
          capital.

      2.   How large are the private investments required by the water
          quality action?   If they are  large,  adjustment  by  the shadow
          price is likely to  be  warranted to  reflect the full opportunity
          costs of these investments.

      3.   What is the nature of the risk associated with  the investment
          and  its relationship to  overall  economic activities?  The answer
          to  this  question  provides  a  basis for  judging  whether  an
          adjument  for  risk should be  made in evaluating  the  project.   If
          most water  quality investments  increase the variability in eco-
          nomic activity for a State  (or the county as a whole), then the
          selection will tend to be at the higher end of the range for the
          social rate of time preference.
     *ln  some cases,  legal restrictions mandate the  use of a  specific rate;
e.g., advanced treatment applications  require  the  applicants to use the Water
Resources Council's rate of 7-7/8 percent.

     tUser  fees  should be  regarded  as  payments  for services provided and
therefore do not displace private investment.
                                 2-18

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     4.   Are  the sources  of  finance  for the project known in advance
          (i.e.,  Federal  sharing of a  local  project's cost)?  Since one
          objective  of benefit-cost  assessment is to  improve the overall
          allocation  of resources, any  Federal share of the  costs should
          be treated  in  the same  way  as the  local share,  with  consid-
          eration given to the full opportunity  costs of the funds used.


     It is impossible to  recommend  a single rate of discount as relevant for all
situations.  Each decision may  well have  special attributes that will need to be
reflected  in the  selection.  It  is important not  to  let the technical  considera-
tions  involved  in  defining the  appropriate discount  rate become overwhelming.
For  most purposes,  the 2 to  6 percent  range of  values  will  be all that  is
necessary.

2.6  Summary

          Intangibles  .should be  viewed from  society's willingness-to-pay
          benchmark even though they are incommensurable.

          Arrays  or  tabular  displays  are  useful  exposition  tools for
          intangibles.

          Household  impacts can  be measured according to ability to pay
          or ability to finance.

          One  measure of ability to pay  is  the ratio  of compliance  costs
          to median  household income.

          Ability to finance is  reflected in a  city's bond market rating in
          the financial community.

          Industrial impacts can affect profits, output, and employment.

          Distribution can  be highlighted  in arrays  showing who receives
          and who bears.

          Discount rates  should  be selected carefully.  Shadow  price of
          capital  should  be  considered  in gauging the full  opportunity
          cost of public investment.

          A sensitivity  analysis  should be  performed  for  the effects of
          selecting the.  discount  rate.  Several  discount  rates should  be
          tried.

          The  implications  of risk  should  be considered for  the discount
          rate.  The relationship between  the  variability of investment or
          outcomes of regulatory policy relative to  variability in national
          income  should  be considered.
                                    2-19

-------
I
                    Net  benefits should  be determined  on a  present value  basis.
                    Formulae and tables should be used.
•             *    Real and nominal discount rates  should not be mixed.
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
2-20

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                 CHAPTER 3

          MEASURING THE BENEFITS OF WATER QUALITY PROGRAMS
3.1  INTRODUCTION

     What  are the  benefits of  water quality  programs?   What are  the basic
benefit principles?  What  methods are available to measure benefits?  What are
the  key assumptions  and  features  of  these  methods?  What case studies are
available to illustrate the use of these1 methods?

     While benefit-cost  assessments that use only  qualitative  information may
suffice for clearcut  water  quality decisions, quantitative information can  simpli-
fy more difficult decisions, by reducing the complexity of  the issues and clari-
fying  the  central issues.   This chapter provides  a framework  for  gathering
and  organizing  this  information to measure the  benefits of water quality pro-
grams.

     This  chapter briefly  reviews the concept  of benefits  and  practical  ap-
proaches  for  measuring  them.   In particular,  it discusses the  conceptual
issues involved in estimating  the benefits of water quality improvements,  de-
scribes techniques  for  measuring  different types  of benefits,  and presents
case studies that show  how different practitioners  have employed them. Spe-
cifically,  Section 3.2 summarizes  benefit  categories,  Section 3.3 highlights
general issues in selecting  a  benefits estimation  methodology,  and Section 3.4
describes approaches for  measuring household benefits.  Section 3.5 discusses
business benefits by summarizing  key aspects in studies of agricultural,  indus-
trial,  and  navigational  benefits of  water  quality  improvement.   Section 3.6
briefly describes public water  supply benefits, and  Section  3.7 summarizes
the  issues  covered  in the  chapter.  Case studies follow  the  text in each of
the  appropriate  sections.   (The  scenarios  in  Chapter 6  show how the case
studies can be applied in new situations.)

3.2  CATEGORIES OF BENEFITS:  AN OVERVIEW

     Since  each  household  or firm undertakes  different  types of activities,
each  is  differently   affected  by  water quality  changes.  A natural starting
point in appraising  the various types of  benefits of water quality programs is
to place them in broad classes.  Figure  3-1  shows the categories of benefits
associated  with water quality  programs.   The top  part  of  the  figure  aligns
each  benefit  type with  the uses made of water  bodies.  More  perspective  on
these  benefit  types is  given by Table 3-1, which  lists them  according  to
households  or firms (the  type of economic agent likely to receive them) and
the methods appropriate for measuring them.   For example,  the user benefits
category separates  health benefits from recreation.  Contingent valuation and
hedonic  property value models  are potential candidates  for  measuring  both
                                    3-1

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
Potential
Water
Quality
Benefits
Current
User
Benefits
Intrinsic
Benefits
Direct
Use
Indirect
Use
Potential
Use
No
Use
1 — Recreational '- fishing, swimming, boating,
rafting, etc.
In Stream _— 1
1 — Commercial — fishing, navigation
1 — Municipal — drinking water, waste disposal
Withdrawal — Agricultural - irrigation
I— Industrial/Commercial — cooling, process treatment,
waste disposal, steam generation
i — Recreational'— hiking, picnicking, birdwatching,
photography, etc.
Near Stream _ Relaxation - viewing
— Aesthetic*- enhancement of adjoining site amenities
i — Near-term potential use
Option' 	 1
1 — Long-term potential use
• — Stewardship - maintaining a good environment for
everyone to enjoy (including future
Existence'^ 	 family use-bequest)
' — Vicarious consumption — enjoyment from the
knowledge that others
are using the resource.
                   Figure 3-1. A spectrum of water .quality benefits.
categories of  benefits.   In  addition,  damage functions  may  be  useful  for
health benefits,  while the travel  cost and  recreation participation survey  ap-
proaches  can measure recreation benefits.

     Although  they are not  directly associated with use, option and existence
values are potential  sources of economic benefits.   Option value is the amount
that an individual may be willing to  pay (over his  expected user values) for
the  right to use a water body--e.g., a  river—in  the  future because uncer-
tainty exists either in the  river's availability  or  in  the individual's  use  of it.
Specifically,  if an individual  thinks he may want  to use the river, but isn't
sure, then he may pay some amount each year for the right to use it.  When
this payment exceeds the benefit the individual would  receive from use,  the
excess is the option  value.  Existence value is the  willingness to pay  simply
for the knowledge that a resource exists--!.e., the  value  an individual places
on a resource just because he  knows it is there.  Thus, because of a steward-
ship or related motive, an individual might be willing to  pay something to  main-
tain  a river even though he knows he will  not use it.

                                      3-2

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                Table 3-1.  Classification of Benefit Categories
Type of
economic
 agent
Benefit  category
   Type of measure-
     ment  method
 Household:   User
  Recreation
Household:   nonuser

Business  and munici-
  pality:  user
  Health



  Option  value

  Existence value

  Cost savings
Travel cost model
Contingent valuation survey
Recreation participation
   survey
Hedonic property value model

Damage function
Contingent valuation survey
Hedonic property value model

Contingent valuation survey

Contingent valuation survey

Cost function
     For  businesses  and  municipalities,  classification  is  more  clearcut:  The
effects  on a  firm's cost  of  production are the  primary  interest because the
role of water  quality  is  exclusively reflected through these effects.   Irriga-
tion,  nagivatio'n, and .process  uses are examples  of water  uses where cost
savings may arise.

     Benefit  classification  should  not  be misinterpreted.   In most'cases  it is
impossible to  separate  all the  sources of  a  benefit  estimate.   For example,
while willingness-to-pay  estimates for  a  water  quality  improvement  derived
from a  hedonic property  value  model  (discussed  below) may be based  on both
direct  and indirect  uses of the water  body,  the contributions  of each cannot
be  shown  in  practice.   Equally important,  overlaps should  be expected  be-
tween  the methods used  and the  types of  benefits  derived.   A  contingent
valuation  survey's (discussed  below)  estimate of willingness to  pay  for  im-
proved  water quality  may  include health, recreational, and  nonuser benefits.
The exact composition will  depend  on  the water body  under  study  and  the
nature of the questions used to elicit the information.

     The  classification scheme offered  in this section simply shows  possible
sources of benefits and may help  identify measurement  methods.   However,
because  this  scheme  does not  fully define each of  the  methods or describe
how a  water quality change is- introduced in each, the following sections offer
more  detailed  discussions  of the various  benefit estimation approaches,  in-
cluding specific case studies that summarize  previous work.
                                    3-3

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
3.3  PRACTICAL CONCERNS: SELECTING A BENEFIT ESTIMATION  METHOD

     One of the first questions  about benefit-cost assessment facing the  prac-
titioner  is how  to  select a method or set of  methods for measuring the  bene-
fits  of water quality programs.   This  decision will  be influenced by the fol-
lowing conditions:

          The time and financial  resources available.

          The types of economic  agents  affected  by  the  change in  water
          quality regulation.

          The nature and  magnitude of the changes  in the water quality
          regulations themselves.

          Data availability.

These conditions largely determine the appropriate level of detail  for a study.
In most  benefit-cost assessments of water quality  programs,.existing data and
results available from other  studies will  be sufficient.  In complex  cases, new
data  and case-specific  methods may be  necessary.  However, even in  these
cases,  when  neither  time  nor   resources are available,  existing  literature
and, to a lesser extent,  ad hoc methods must be used.*

     In  practice, the ideal conditions routinely assumed in theoretical analyses
of benefit measures simply  do  not exist.  Indeed, many benefit analyses  of
environmental resources result in compromises that arise from a  poor under-
standing of the exact association  between water  quality and  particular activ-
ities of  economic  agents.  However, while compromises may  be  necessary  to
measure  the  benefits  of  water  quality  regulations  for  some water  bodies,
every  effort should  be  made to measure  benefits  based on willingness to pay
and  cost savings—the  only  definitions for economic benefits  that  have clear
theoretical justifications.

     Finally,  because resources are limited, benefit-cost  assessments of  water
quality programs  require  that resources be  wisely used—i.e., that they be
closely matched  with the  complexity of  specific  cases.  Whether or not re-
sources  are available,  however,  the practitioner  must  clearly understand the
features  of  each   benefit  measurement method to  make  an intelligent  choice
among them.
     *For example,  while  the  Water Resources Council's current guidelines for
cost-benefit  analysis,  recommend  use of the  travel  cost  or  contingent  valua-
tion  approach for estimating economic benefits  of outdoor recreation services,
they  acknowledge that  practitioners may  have to  use ad hoc approximations
such  as  activity-day values—constant dollar  values proposed for days of  par-
ticular types of  outdoor recreation (see Water  Resources  Council  [1979])—
multiplied by projections of user-days.
                                    3-4

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 3.4   HOUSEHOLD BENEFITS

      There are  several ways to measure the benefits  of water quality pro-
 grams.  However,  to compare the accuracy of* these measures, the practitioner
 must  also understand how  individuals  value different  goods.  Fortunately,
 economics  provides an objective way to  measure these values using  the basic
 concept of a demand function.

 Theory:   The  Demand  Function

      The first organizational guidepost that economics provides  is the concept
 of an individual demand  function,  shown in  Figure  3-2.   This function  de-
 scribes  for  any good, X,  the  maximum  quantity of the  good an  individual
 would be willing to purchase for each price of X.  The downward slope of the
 curve indicates that individuals are willing to buy more of X at lower prices
 than  at  higher  prices.  The simple diagram in Figure 3-2 assumes  all other
 factors that might  influence  demand—including  income,  the prices of  related
 goods, etc.--do  not change.  Frequently, there is no need  to  actually meas-
 ure  a .demand  curve.  What it does  is provide a basis from which the benefits
 to households can be viewed.
                                                       time
                Figure 3-2.  The demand function and consumer surplus.
     If  the  market process establishes a  price at P  , the individual will  pur-
chase Q  of X and make a total  expenditure equal l8 P AQ O.  Since the area
under tne demand  curve measures the individual's maxfrnun? willingness to pay
for each unit  of consumption, the total willingness to pay for Q  is the entire
area—total  expenditures plus the  triangle  P P.A.   This difference—between
                                            o  j
                                   3-5

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 what the individual  actually pays  and the amount he is willing to pay--is  the
 consumer surplus,  or the dollar measure of the satisfaction an individual  re-
 ceives from  consuming a good or service, less what he pays for it.  As a dol-
 lar  measure of  individual welfare, consumer  surplus  is  not ideal,  but most
 studies have found it to be a good benchmark.

 Practice:  Methods for Measuring Household  Benefits

     Household benefits  may be measured  by  using the travel cost method,  a
 contingent  valuation  survey, a recreation  participation survey,  the  hedonic
 property value method,  or the  damage function method.   Advantages and dis-
 advantages,  data requirements,  and key  assumptions of each method are  high-
 lighted in this section.  Case studies show  how the methods have  been used
 in recent applications.

 Travel Cost  Method

     One of  the most popular approaches to describe demand for  the  services
 of recreation facilities, the travel  cost  model,* has been used to estimate  re-
 creational  benefits  in a  wide  variety of applications.   The -logic underlying
 this model  is  simple. Recreators  at  a  particular site  pay  an  "implicit"  price
 for  using the  site's  services through  the travel and time costs associated with
 visiting  that site.f   Since  recreators visit a  site from diverse origins,  their
 "travel behavior" can be used  to  analyze  the demand  for the site's services.
 That is,  all else being  equal,  any person  will continue to travel to  the site
 until the marginal  value  of the  last trip  is  exactly  equal to its full  costs
 (i.e.,  the travel expenses  and  the opportunity cost of the time spent travel-
 ing).

     As  a rule, the travel cost  model  estimates the demand for the representa-
 tive individual.  Therefore,  to  estimate  the  aggregate  benefits of water  qual-
 ity improvement  at a  site,  the practitioner  needs to  estimate how many  recrea-
 tors would  use  it.    The solution  to  this  problem will  depend  upon the data
 used to  estimate individual  demand.   For example,  the visits  made by  resi-
 dents of an origin zone,  usually during a season, relative to the population of
 that origin  zone  is .the  quantity measure—a  rate of use--conventibnally used
 in the travel cost model.  Since benefits are for the "representative"  rate of
 use, multiplying by  the  population of that origin zone will yield its aggregate
 benefit estimates.  Overall benefits would be the sum of the zone  benefit esti-
 mates .
     *For further details see Dwyer, Kelly, and Bowes [1977], Freeman  [1979],
Smith [1975], and Desvousges,  Smith, and McGivney  [1983].

     fMost public recreation facilities either  have no user fees or have nomi-
nal fees that do not reflect the marginal cost of a site's recreation  services.
Thus,  these fees are hot indicative of the equilibrium prices that would arise
if conventional market mechanisms allocated the services of recreation sites.
                                      3-6

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
     Travel  cost  models also can  be estimated  by surveying users at a specific
recreation site.   Then,  the benefit estimates are for a "representative" recre-
ationist and  estimates of total  site use estimates, must be obtained independent-
ly.  Possible sources  of these estimates include the Corps of Engineers,  the
Department  of  Interior,  or  parks  and  recreation  departments at  the State
level.

     If a travel cost model  can be estimated,  it.can be  used to estimate con-
sumer surplus.   However,  this  is only  part  of  the problem that must  be
solved to  appraise the  benefits  of water quality improvements.   In addition,
the  linkages  between the  regulations,  the changes  in  water quality, and  the
recreation decisions of individuals  must be  known.   One  possible linkage is a
change in demand  for  the  services  of a recreation site  because individuals
wish  to  use  them in one or  more activities.  A  change  in  the  level of water
quality may  permit a wider  range of uses, increase the individual's  enjoyment
(and  hence valuation) of existing uses,  or  both, which  increases the  demand
for the site's  services at each (implicit)  price.

     Therefore,  to  evaluate the implications of a change  in  water quality for
an  individual's  economic well-being, water quality must be linked to the vari-
ables in  a recreation demand function.  Three  ways for making this association
will be discussed in detail  in  Volume II.   The case shown in Figure .3-3 offers
the most  acceptable approach  for  linking  water quality to recreation site de-
mand.   It incorporates the  effects of  water  quality as  a determinant  of the
demand in the  travel  cost model  for a  site's services  (see Freeman  [1979],
Chapter 8).   Since little evidence  generally exists  on the  variation in  water
                Implicit
                Price  E
                $/visit
                                        WQ«>WQ
                                               Demand (WQ«)



                                               Demand (WO)
                      0           Q1     Q2         Quantity of
                          Water Quality Treated as a Demand Change  v'S't*/Y«»r


                     Figure 3-3. Illustration of the treatment of water
                         quality with travel cost demand model.
                                      3-7

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
quality across  the  same water body, the travel cost model  is difficult to imple-
ment  empirically  with a  single  site.   Conceptually,  however,  a  change  in
water  quality is assumed  to  shift site  demand  by  providing  a  wider ranger of
activities.   Thus,  in  Figure 3-3, the  benefits associated  with a change from
WQ to WQ* would  be  represented by the  area HGFE.   The  scenario in Chap-
ter 6  shows an existing  study  that  can  be  applied  to  new situations  (see
Chapter 6, Section 6.4).

Data Needs,  Key Assumptions/Limitations,  and  Features

     The following checklist  outlines the data  needs and key assumptions and
features of the travel cost model.

Data Needs:

          Origin—county  of  residence  or  zip code—for  users of the
          recreation  site.   These   are often  available  from  recreation
          management agencies for samples of users.

          Population size and summary  measures for features of the popu-
          lation in each origin zone (e.g.,  median family  income, median
          age,   and  median  education).   Sources  include  census  data,
          national and State recreation surveys, and site surveys.

          Round-trip  mileage from  each origin  to  site.  This  information
          can be calculated from maps.

          Vehicle  costs per mile and implicit time costs of travel.  Travel
          costs  should be calculated as operating  costs  per mile  for the
          vehicle.  Time  costs can be estimated  with  the approximate
          wage  rate for the  household  head.  One source is a wage and
          occupation survey.

Key  Assumptions/Limitations and Features:

          The  model  is site  specific.  It measures  the  demand for the
          services of a site, not total or general recreation demand.

          The model measures only user  benefits.

          Consistency  in  the length of  stay for each  type of trip in ag-
          gregate data.  For example,  all  trips are treated as day  visits
          or as weekend visits.

          A site's  demand  depends  on  its potential services for the re-
          quired activities.   (For  example,  a  minimum-sized  river  seg-
         .ment   is  necessary for power boating,  while  a  river  segment
          with extensive locks and dams  is not conducive to canoeing.)

          The cost of time spent at the site is excluded.  This suggests
          that  "full-cost"  may  not  be  expressed  in a demand relation-
          ship.

                                    3-8

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
          There are no  good substitute  sites available.  If many substi-
          tutes are available,  the simple  model  will overstate the demand
          for the site.

          The travel cost  is assumed to capture  all  the factors  that  in-
          fluence  the  decision to  recreate  at  the site.   (For example,
          this assumption  implies  that  no changes in  access,  docks, or
          other site features occur.)

          The only purpose of the trip  is  to  recreate at the  site.   If
          this is  not the case, the cost of the trip  has a joint cost and
          benefits are overestimated.
          * •
         CASE STUDY:   ALTERNATIVE  APPROACHES  FOR  ESTIMATING
                   RECREATION AND .RELATED  BENEFITS OF
                          THE MONONGAHELA RIVER*

 I ntroduction

     The travel  cost  model  for the  Monongahela River study  assumes that site
features or  attributes affect the  individual's ability to participate in  recrea-
tional  activities  at  any  particular site, as well  as the quality of the  recrea-
tional .activities undertaken.  It considers  the demand for a  recreation site as
a  derived demand.   That  is,  a  site's  services  are  desired because of the
recreational  activities  that  can  be undertaken at  that  site.  Common sense
suggests that  a  recreation  site's  features  or attributes will  influence the de-
mand for its  services.   Since  the level of water quality  is a site attribute, a
basis is  established  for relating  water  changes  to  shifts  in demand for a
recreation site's services.

Approach

     The measurement  approach  examined numerous  water-based  recreation
sites from the Federal Estate Survey component of the 1977 National Outdoor
Recreation Survey.  This survey provides specific information on the sample
recreationist  patterns of use during  a  single  season  for  each  site.   The
sample  sizes for  each site  ranged  from approximately 30 to several hundred
respondents  and included  information  on individuals'  recreation  behavior,
socioeconomic characteristics,  travel  time necessary to  reach the site, residen-
tial location/  and a variety  of other factors.  This information permitted the
estimation of  individual travel cost  demand models for each  of the  recreation.
sites.
                                            x
     Several  advantages of this travel-cost model  include:
     *This discussion is taken from Desvousges, Smith, and McGivney [1983].
                                  3-9

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
           Deriving  individual " estimates   for  the  time  associated  with
           traveling to the  site as well as  the roundtrip distance for each
           trip.

           Using the opportunity  cost of time to  evaluate travel time and
           estimating  opportunity cost for each  individual  based  on his
           characteristics,  including age, education, race, sex,  and occu-
           pation.

           Considering for  each  site  the   potential  effects of individuals'
           differences in onsite time per visit.

     A total  of 22 individual site  demand functions  were estimated based on
 this survey.   For example,  Equation  (3.1) is  a general description  of  one of
 these  site demand models:
                              In V ~ a + bTC  + cY,
(3.1)
 where
     In V  = the  natural -log of the  number of visits  by  a  household to
            the site in a recreation season.

      TC = the travel cost per  visit to the site, including out-of-pocket
            vehicle operating costs and the opportunity cost of the time
            spent traveling.

       Y  = family income.

     The basic hypothesis  of  this study is that  variation in the estimates of
a,  b,  and c  across  sites reflects  the .effects of those sites'  characteristics on
the  representative  individual's demand  for each  site's services.   Thus,  each
estimate provides  the  basis  for  describing how a  change  in  any  attribute
would affect demand.

     The second  step in the  study  involved estimating  the relationship be-
tween  variations in the .site-specific estimates of a, b, and  c and  each  site's
attributes.  The  site  characteristic  information was obtained from  records of
the  U.S.  Army Corps of Engineers  and the water  quality data from the  U.S.
Geological  Survey.  Table 3-2  reports the  site attributes, including the  water
quality measures  used  in  the model.   Many  other attributes,  such  as  boat
launches, docks,  and recreational  facilities, were tried,  but none  was statis-
tically significant.   For sites where the information on water quality was incom-
plete,  the average value for  all  sites was used.  This  treatment of missing
values means  that the estimated relationships  will rely primarily on sites with
observed readings for the water quality  variables.

     Since precision  in  the estimates  of demand parameters a,  b, and  c in
Equation  (3.1)  varied, a statistical procedure was used  to account  for the
quality  of the  estimates.   Table  3-3  shows the  estimated equations  for the
demand parameters.   As Table 3-3 shows,  many of the attributes have statis-
tically significant effects on the  demand parameters, particularly on the travel
                                    3-10

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
      Table 3-2.  Site Attributes Considered in  Monongahela River Study
 Variable
  name
              Description
      Source
SHMILEa


ACCESS8



ARSIZE3



D0a'b
Number of miles of shoreline for the site


Number of developed  multipurpose recrea-
  tional areas  plus the number of  developed
  access areas on  the site

The ratio of the pool  surface acreage
  during the peak visiting period  relative
  to the total project  area  in acres

Dissolved oxygen based on monthly
  readings
U.S. Army Corps
  of Engineers

U.S. Army Corps
  of Engineers


U.S. Army Corps
  of Engineers


U.S. Geological
  Survey
 These  variables  were  considered  as  monthly  readings  and as  4-month
 averages in the specification of the demand parameter models.
 K
 DOM  and DOV  correspond  to the average value of dissolved oxygen over the
 four monthly observations and the variance about that average, respectively.
     Table 3-3.  Estimated Equations  for Site Demand  Parameter Estimates*
Variable
Intercept term

SHMILE

ACCESS

ARSIZE

Average DO

Variance in DO


A
a
1.51
(4.08)
0.0003
(1.25)
-0.0059
(-1.50)
-0.395
(-1.75)
0.0045
(1.07)
0.0005
(1.86)
Site demand parameter
6
-0.0246
(-9.48)
-0.00001
(-6.76)
0.00008
(2.81)
0.0033
(2.27)
0.00018
(5.99)
0.00001
(4.08)
estmates
c
0.000005
(0.308)
9.74 x 10~10
(0.09)
4.69 x 10~7
(2.56)
-1.94 x 10~6
(-0.18)
-1.22 x 10"7
(-0.60)
9.39 x 10"11
(0.01)
a
 The  numbers  in  parentheses  below  the  estimated coefficients are the asymp-
 totic  (approximate)  t-ratios  for  the  null  hypothesis  of no  association—the
 larger the number,  the more likely the hull hypothesis is  rejected.  These
 equations  show  how the  parameters of  the individual site demand  equations
 vary with  changes in the site's attributes.
                                     3-11

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
cost parameter.  The water quality attribute  has  a  highly significant effect oh
travel  costs,  with  the most plausible results  obtained  using the mean value of
dissolved oxygen over the 4-month  summer period  (June through September)
and  the variance  in  dissolved  oxygen about that  mean.  However,  the small
variation  in the  water quality  measures over  the sample suggests these find-
ings be interpreted cautiously.

     The model was  used to evaluate  the benefits of a water quality improve-
ment for  users of  the Monongahela  River in  Pennsylvania.   This site was not
included in the 22. used  to estimate the  model.   The model was  applied  to an
independent data set based on  a household survey  of  residents in the Monon-
gahela  River  Basin (see  the case study  under Contingent Valuation  below for
more details). The survey reported sufficient information on  the  respondents'
socioeconbmic  characteristics,  as well as specific portion(s)  of the river used,
to construct  individual demand  curves  varying by  river site (at a total  of 13
different sites) and by individual.  The  benefit calculations were as follows:

          Estimates, of consumer surplus  loss  per user if the  river were
          no longer available for its current use—recreational boating.

     •  '  Estimates of the  increment to consumer surplus associated  with
        • improving  water  quality  from  the  current  level that  permits
          boating,  to a .level that would  accommodate  recreational fishing.

          Estimates of the  increment to consumer surplus associated  with
          improving  water  quality from the current level (boating)  to a
          level that would accommodate swimming.

     The  levels of dissolved  oxygen  used in  the .benefit calculations for each
of these use designations were the values  selected by Vaughan in Mitchell and
Carson  [1982] in  a  water quality  ladder developed  for  Resources for the
Future  (RFF).  The  variance  in dissolved oxygen was held.constant at levels
corresponding to those generally observed at  the  22  sites.   Table  3-4 provides
the RFF ladder thresholds for each activity.

           Table 3-4.  Specifications for  the  Dissolved Oxygen (DO)
                   Levels Associated  With  Use  Designations
             Use
          designation
      DO level
(percent saturation)
Beatable
Fishable .
Swimmable
Drinkable
45
64
83
90
           These  thresholds  correspond  to  those  used  in  RFF's
           water quality ladder.

          3These  use   designations  were  considered  for  benefit
           analyses.
                                     3-12

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 Benefit  Estimation

      Figure 3-4 illustrates  the  model.  DCWQt)  corresponds to the representa-
 tive  individual's demand for the  site's  services at a  water  quality level  of
 WQj.  Since the demand function is specified as semi-log  in quantity, there is
 no maximum price  at which  visits to the  site  will  be zero.  Therefore,  the
 benefit  calculation  required a maximum feasible  price--P*.  This  was taken to
 correspond to  the  largest  travel  cost incurred  by  any  of the  users  of  the
 Monongahela River ($22.65 per roundtrip).
                    $/viiit
                P* - $22.65
                                                   D(WQ2)
                                                         In visit
                                                          yr
                 Figure 3^4.General travel^ost demand-model lor a water
                               quality improvement.
     The first benefit calculation  involves the computation of the baseline area
P.ABP*—the loss in  consumer surplus if  the .site could no  longer  provide the
services available with  a water quality of WQj  to  the user with a travel cost
of P..   Incremental benefit estimates  were derived  by estimating  the addition
to consumer surplus  associated with the  increment  to water quality.   In Fig-
ure 3-4, a  change from WQX  to WQ2  would  be  shown  as  leading to  an incre-
mental  benefit of ACDB for the user  at  a travel cost of P..  Table 3-5  pro-
vides  a summary  of the  average benefit estimate  for each  change  and  the
range of estimates over the survey respondents.

     This case  study provides a detailed model  for incorporating site  attri-
butes  into  estimating the  demand  for water-based  recreation sites  and,  in
turn,  for  evaluating  the  benefits from changing one  or  more of those  attri-
butes.   Since  It was developed from  data  primarily  on flat-water recreation
sites,  the  model can  be used to predict benefits for changes  in attributes for
a  sizable range of  recreation  sites.   However,  the  actual  estimates of  the
benefits of  water  quality  improvements  in  the study must  be regarded  as
tentative because of  the limited  available information  on  water quality.   The
approach illustrated  by  this  case study  could be  used in a  wide variety of
applications.  For one example, see Chapter 6, Section  6.4;
                                      3-13

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
            Table  3-5:  Benefit Estimates .from  Generalized Travel
            Cost Model With  the Monongahela Survey  Respondents
                                                          Benefits'
       Use designations
 Mean
    Range
 Benefits lost as a result of the loss
  of ability to  undertake boating
  activities

 Incremental benefits gained as a
  result of water quality improvement
  changing use designation from
  boatable to fishable

 Incremental benefits gained as a
  result of water quality improvement
  changing use designation from
  boatable to swimmable
$53.35
$ 4.52
$ 9.49
0 to $70.80
0 to $8.60
0 to $18.30
 The benefits are  measured as the consumer surplus per  user for the use of
 the river during a single recreational season.
Survey—Contingent Valuation

     The  contingent  valuation survey  approach for  estimating the benefits- as-
sociated  with a  nonmarketed  commodity  such as water  quality  improvements
involves  asking individuals about  their willingness  to  pay for different levels
of the commodity  involved.   Use  of the survey approach  requires that the
practitioner determine the aspects  of changes in  environmental quality individ-
uals  value and  convey  these aspects to the  respondent.  The  approach as-
sumes  that individuals  will  accurately reveal  their valuation of  potential be-
havioral  responses  in  hypothetical  market  experiments.  These experiments
depend on a survey procedure and a survey instrument.  The survey proce-
dure  determines  the appropriate sampling plan  and specifies the general re-
quirements of the survey  instrument.  The survey instrument is  the  question-
naire used to elicit the respondents' answers.

     A survey instrument is  the  cornerstone of the hypothetical  market used
in the contingent valuation survey approach.   It will  generally consist of the
following sections  [Rowe  and Chestnut, 1981.]:

          Introduction and statement of purpose

          Nonvaluation questions
                                   3-14

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
          Scenario development and market definition

          Bidding or valuation questions.

The first two sections are self explanatory.and will  not be  discussed further.
The scenario .development and  market definition section is considered the most
critical  aspect of survey instruments because  it  must carefully  present the
alternative  levels of  environmental quality.   In  the  case of water  quality,
scenario development describes the linkages between the regulatory  action and
the resulting.change in  water quality.  Verbal or written descriptions, supple-
mented  by visual  props, are  used in  this activity.  Scenario development must
be  informative and  realistic.   It  must portray the probabilities of the effects,
as well as the effects themselves.

     After the hypothetical  scenario  is developed  and the market  is defined,
the bidding or valuation of the environmental commodity takes place.  Several
questioning formats can be used:

          Pi rect Question - - The interviewer directly asks the  individual's
          willingness to  pay  for a specified  change in the amount of a
          commodity—water quality--that  has  been carefully defined.  No
          cards or other aids  are  used to obtain the amounts.

          Bidding Game—The interviewer  defines the change to be evalu-
          ated,  suggests  to  the individual an amount representing the
          value of the change  (the starting point), and asks  whether he
          would .be  willing  to pay that amount.  Based on the response,
          the interviewer  raises  or  lowers  the  suggested  value   by  a
          fixed  amount  and   repeats  the  process  until  the individual
          agrees no  further change is  necessary.

     *     Payment Card—This approach also  does  not  directly ask about
          willingness  to  pay.   The  interviewer  explains  the  specified
          change  to  be  evaluated, provides  the  individual with a card
          displaying  an  array of potential values,  and asks him to select
          a value  or give any  value for willingness to pay.  These  num-
          bers range from  zero to values judged to be outside the range
         .of  responses.   Some   surveys   (notably  Mitchell  and  Carson
          [1981])  have adjusted the upper bounds  of values on the cards
          for  higher income  respondents.  In addition,  in an  anchored
          payment card  format,  some  responses have  been identified as
          reflecting  the  share of  an individual's taxes associated with
          specific  public programs, such  as  education  and defense (see
          Mitchell  and Carson [1981])-

          Bidding  Game  With  Budget Constraint—This approach is a very
          recent  innovation  for  the  bidding  game  format  discussed in
          Brookshire et  al. [1982].  Before requesting a  bid  in the for-
          mat explained  above,  the  interviewer  asks the  individual to
          estimate his after-tax  monthly  income and  allocate  it into ex-
          penditure  categories--for example,  electricity,  shelter, enter-
                                  3-15

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
•.
I
I
          tainrrient, savings,  and  a  residual.  After  this  information is
          acquired,  the interviewer conducts a  bidding  game with  an
          additional question:   "Which  of the categories  of expenditures
          would be reduced in order to make the proposed  payment?"

          Ranked Choice and Willingness  to  Pay--ln this approach, intro-
        -  duced  by Rae  [1981a, T981b], the interviewer provides individ-
          uals with different hypothetical market outcomes—proposed  pay-
          ments  and  a  specified  level or  change  in  water quality, for
          example, to be ranked.   These ranks are then used in a statis-
          tical analysis to estimate the individual's willingness to  pay.

The question format and description of the hypothetical  market are  important
determinants  of the quality of the estimates derived  from a contingent valua-
tion experiment.   The results of a  comparative analysis of the direct  question,
payment card, and bidding game formats in Desvousges,  Smith, and  McGivney
[1983]  suggest that,  for questions associated  with water  quality,  the question
format  has  some effect  on  the average willingness to pay.  The starting point
for the bidding game appears to  influence  the average values.

     Two basic types of biases can arise in designing the  format of a contin-
gent  valuation study.  Since Schulze,  d'Arge,  and  Brookshire [1981],  Rowe
and Chestnut  [1981], and  Mitchell  and Carson [1981]  have  all discussed  these
biases in detail,  a brief  overview of their conclusions  is provided in Table 3-6,
which  defines the  bias, identifies the  studies that  considered  its  potential
effects,  and summarizes the current understanding of its effects.

     Overall, the results seem to suggest  that starting point bias may be the
most important consideration (aside from the hypothetical nature of  the ques-
tions,  which has not received sufficient testing to  fully gauge its  implications)
in  using the  contingent valuation  framework.   Most  of  the other  potential
sources  of bias can be controlled in the structuring of the  instrument and the
explanations  provided  to  sample  respondents.   Several additional  technical
assumptions  are  highlighted below  in a summary of data requirements and  key
assumptions of the approach.

Data Needs,  Key Assumptions/Limitations, and Features

     The following checklist outlines the data needs for the contingent valua-
tion survey approach, along with its key assumptions and features.
Data Needs:
          Survey  of  individuals designed to be representative of affected
          population.

          Clearly  defined  and pretested survey instrument.   In-person
          interviews  are generally more  reliable than telephone  or  mail
          surveys.
                                 3-16

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                    Table 3-6.  Summary of Biases in Contingent  Valuation Experiments
Type of bias
             Definition
                                                              Studies that have
                                                               tested  for bias
                            Summary of
                          current results
General
    Hypothetical
Error introduced by  posing  hypothetical
  conditions  rather than actual condi-
  tions  to an individual; response may
  not be a good guide to actual actions
  individual  would take
One known  test--
  Bishop-Heberlin
  [1979]
    Strategic
Attempt by respondents to influence out-
  come of study by systematically over-
  or under-bidding  so action favors
  their true interests; strategic
  responses depend on how  payment scheme
  is defined and whether it  is believed
At  least eight tests
  (see Schulze,
  d'Arge, and
  Brookshire [1981]
  for summary;
  Cronin  [1982])
Instrument
Related
    Starting
      point
Contingent valuation  experiments  using
  bidding game format have  started with
  suggested payment and use yes or no
  responses to derive final willingness
  to pay; suggestion may be perceived as
  appropriate  bid
At least five tests
  (see Schulze,
  d'Arge, and
  Brookshire [1981]
  and  Rowe and
  Chestnut  [1981])
    Vehicle
    Information
    Interviewer
Characteristics of proposed mechanism   •
  for obtaining respondent's willingness
  to pay may influence responses
Effect of information provided to
  respondent on costs of action under
  study or other dimensions of  problem
  may affect  responses
Responses vary systematically  according
  to  interviewer
At least four tests
  (see Schulze,
  d'Arge, and
  Brookshire [1981]
  and Mitchell and
  Carson  [1982])

At least four tests
  (see Schulze,
  d'Arge, and
  Brookshire [1981]
  and Mitchell and
  Carson  [1981])

Two  tests--
  Desvousges,  Smith,
  and McGivney
  {1983]  and
  Cronin [1982])
Some indication that
  hypothetical  nature
  of question did
  influence responses,
  but could not dis-
  tinguish this effect
  from instrument-
  related  biases

Very little evidence
  of strategic bias
  except for Cronin
  [1982]
Some differences in
  opinion over impor-
  tance of starting
  point bias;
  Mitchell-Carson
  feel  starting point
  bias is important,
  and  Desvousges,
  Smith, and  McGivney
  [1983] provide some
  support; Schulze,
  d'Arge, and
  Brookshire  [1981]
  feel  it is more
  limited

Some evidence of
  effects in at
  least two studies
                                                                                      Limited evidence of
                                                                                       effects
                                                                                     No evidence of bias
                                                                                     Bias present
 The definitions and  results summarized in  this table are based on Schulze, d'Arge,  and Brookshire [1981],
 Rowe and Chestnut [1981], and Mitchell and Carson [1981].
                                                    3-17

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Key Assumptions/Limitations and Features:

          Individuals' responses to hypothetical questions are assumed to
          be  indicative  of their  actual  valuations of the  changes  de-
          scribed in the questions.

          Careful tests  are  required  to determine  starting point effects,
          appropriate mechanisms  for  payment, and  consistency of re-
          sponses with other budgetary requirements.

          Careful Control  is required over  information given  respondents
          so answers are based  on the  same information in each inter-
          view.

****************

            CASE STUDY:  RECREATION AND  RELATED BENEFITS
                OF  WATER QUALITY IMPROVEMENTS  OF THE
                           MONONGAHELA  RIVER*

Introduction

     This  contingent valuation  survey  measured  the recreation  and related
benefits  of water  quality improvements  in the Monongahela River  Basin  in
Pennsylvania.  It compared alternative question  formats for asking individuals'
willingness  to .pay and measured  both user and nonuser values.  In  a house-
hold  survey conducted  by  9 professional  interviewers from  the five-county
area,  an 80 percent response rate  was obtained  from a  clustered random
sample of 393 households.

Approach

     In any contingent  valuation  study,  the  survey questionnaire is the key
element for providing plausible results.   By dividing  the questionnaire into a
version for each question format and  distributing  each version  equally among
the interviewers, the Monongahela study compared the techniques,

     A  water  quality ladder,  developed by  RFF  (see  the  travel  cost  case
study  for  more  detail),  was used  to  establish a  linkage between   levels  of
water quality  and the associated  uses for recreation.  Tied to scientific meas-
ures of water quality, the ladder  steps permit the  respondent to give his will-
ingness to pay  for the various levels of water quality.

     The contingent  valuation method requires a way to make the hypothetical
payment  for water quality improvements.  User  fees, increases  in sales taxes,
and  increases  in water  bills  are among the alternatives used.  This study
expressed the  additional annual amounts as  taxes and  higher consumer prices.
Also used  by  Mitchell  and Carson [1981],  this method  corresponds roughly
with how a  respondent actually pays for water quality improvements.
     *This discussion is taken from Desvousges, Smith, and McGivney [1983].


                                     3-18

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
      Each version of the questionnaire used  a different technique  to elicit the
 respondent's willingness to pay.  The iterative bidding  technique  was  used in
 two versions, with the interviewer  starting the bidding at $25 in  one  version
 and at $125 in  another.  The direct question  techniques and the payment card
 were also used.  The payment card contained values arrayed from $5 to $775,
 but no other information.

      All  versions  of the  questionnaire  required  the  respondent to  place  a
 value on a  degradation  in water  quality in the Monongahela  from  its  present
 overall level of beatable to  a level  where the  river was  unsuitable  for any
 recreation.   Additional  amounts were elicited for water quality improvements
 to  support  fishing  and swimming.   These amounts  reflected  actual  use and
 potential  use in the future,  with  a followup question requiring the respondent
 to break down the amounts into actual and potential use.

. Benefit Estimation

      For  each  version  of  the questionnaire,  Table 3-7 presents the  average
 amounts users  and nbnusers  of the Monongahela River  were willing to  pay for


       Table  3-7.  Willingness to Pay for Three Levels of Water Quality9
                                    ($/yr)
                                Users
                              Nonusers
   Combined
 Mean
 Standard deviation
 Number  of respondents
              Payment card
           117.9 (47.1)           82.8
           117.0 (53.8)          104.7
            17                   37
 93.8 (71.6)
108.9 (92.8)
 54
Mean
Standard deviation
Number  of respondents
             Direct question

           98.2 (47.4)            34.5
          103.5 (81.5)            66.4
           17                    34
 55.7 (38.8)
 85.2 (71.8)
 51
                  Bidding Game:  $25 starting point

Mean                        59.5  (42.4)            51.4
Standard deviation           38.1  (31.9)            53.1
Number  of respondents       19                     39
                                                54.1  (48.4)
                                                48.5  (47.1)
                                                58
Mean
Standard deviation
Number
Bidding Game:   $125  starting point

          194.4 (109.4)           79.2
          136.5 (129.2)          102.5
           16                    32
117.6 ( 89.3)
126.0 (111.6)
 48
 As defined in  Section 3.2, numbers in parentheses are individuals' estimated
 mean option values and corresponding standard deviations.
                                   3-19

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
avoiding a  decrease in  water quality and for raising it  to  swimmable levels.*
Several  conclusions  can be  drawn  from the  results in Table 3-7.  The esti-
mates  of willingness to pay—regardless of method used  to  elicit the amount—
are  quite  substantial,  ranging from  $35  to $195  per  year.  The  results are
sensitive to the method used; the payment card  with  the  $125  starting  point
bidding  game gave higher amounts than the direct question  with the $25 start-
ing  point  bidding game,  there  is  some indication  of a starting  point  bias,
but the evidence is not conclusive.

     Users  of the  Monongahela generally were  willing  to pay higher amounts
than  nonusers, with  their average  values  ranging from  $59 to  $194 compared
to a  nonuser  range  of  $34  to $83.   Estimates of option value are about half
the  user's  willingness-to-pay values  and  are statistically significant for both
users  and nonusers.   The results imply that  benefit estimates based solely on
recreation  use may substantially understate the total benefits of water quality
improvements.  The  approach illustrated by  this  case  study could be used in
a wide variety of applications. .For one example,  see Larson  [1981].
Survey--Recreatioh Participation Models

     Many State and  Federal agencies undertake surveys of the general  popu-
lation  in  an  effort to identify  household participation  patterns for recreational
activities.  As  a rule,  these  surveys provide  detailed information  on house-
hold characteristics and on the  types  and amounts of participation  in outdoor
recreation.   These surveys have been  used to .estimate recreation participation
models.   Such  models are neither demand nor  supply relationships but sum-
maries  of all the determinants  of the  likelihood that  an  individual  will  parti-
cipate  in  recreational activities—for  example, boating, fishing,  or swimming--
as  well as  of the level'of participation  in these activities.  Generally,  these
models  divide the  participation decision  into two steps:  determining  whether
a person  participates in a particular activity and modeling the expected num-
ber of days (or trips) he spends  at the.activity over  a season.

     These models have been developed from a  framework that  views the indi-
vidual   as  maximizing well-being by  selecting  levels of  service flows for  his
consumption.   Individuals  produce these service flows by  using  time and/or
purchased goods and services.   For example,  the  level of participation in a
recreation activity is one  measure of recreation  service flow that requires the
person's time, any equipment associated  with the activity, and  the services of
a  recreation  site  as  inputs.   Participation models,  which  describe the final
result  of the  activity,  are influenced  by each. element  in the production of
service flows.
     *These  mean amounts are  calculated exclusive of the  respondents  who
rejected  the approach and those  who were shown  to  be outliers by a statis-
tical  analysis.   For   a  complete  discussion of  the procedures  used  to  make
these determinations  and the small differences that result from the exclusions,
see Desvousges,  Smith, and McGivney  [1983].
                                      3-20

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     This  perspective  is  important  because it establishes a natural  association
between participation and travel cost models.   Travel  cost models are demand
models  for the  services  of a recreation  site.   These  services add to the  pro-
duction of the  recreation  service flows.  In addition,  benefits  measured  by a
participation model  should, for consistency, use the demand for the  recreation
service flow and  not for the recreation site,  but  these demands are difficult
to isolate.*  This often  makes assignments  of  benefit  estimates resulting  from
a  change  in  water  quality arbitrary  (see   Davidson,  Adams, and Seneca
[1966]).

     Instead of  identifying  the  recreation  facilities  used  by the survey, re-
spondents,  participation   surveys  have, as a rule,  required crude measures of
recreation  supply characteristics to  be merged.   In  principle, this merging
permits the  use  of  summary measures  of  water quality for regional areas as
determinants of  the likely participation and  the level  of  participation of the
representative  household.  Yielding crude approximations  at best,  this prac-
tice reflects the paucity of data in this area.

     However water quality is  introduced, it  should  be emphasized that the
results of  these models  are estimates of the levels of use of recreation activi-
ties  and not economic  benefits.  Methods for  measuring these  values must be
developed independently.

Data Needs,  Key  Assumptions/Limitations, and  Features

     The  following checklist outlines  the data needs  for the participation  sur-
vey method, along with its key assumptions  and features.

Data Needs:

          Survey of recreation  patterns of the genera! population,  with
          socioeconomic  detail and   identification  of  residential  location
          (preferably in  more detail  than State of residence).

          Identification of sites used for recreation activities, or at  least
          some  measure  of the  supply  of  recreation  facilities,  is highly
          desirable.           .

          Measures  of  water quality  for sites  used  by respondents,  or
          linkage between  water  quality and   capacity-related  measures
          for recreational activities.

Key Assumptions/Limitations and  Features:

          An independent estimate  is required  of an individual's willing-
          ness  to pay  for  a day  or  a trip  spent  in  each recreational
          activity.
     *See Deyak and Smith [1978] and Bockstael and McConnell [1981].
                                      3-21

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
          The demand  and supply relationships are  assumed  to  remain
          stable.

          Model  specification  (i.e.,  two-step  partition  of  participation
          decision  and  level of  participation) is assumed to be correct,
          and  functional forms  are assumed to be  adequate approxima-
          tions.

          Measures  should  be provided  at a general level, not  on  a site-
          specific basis.
****************


          CASE STUDY:  A PARTICIPATION SURVEY APPROACH  TO
                  VALUING WATER QUALITY IMPROVEMENTS* ,

Introduction and Basic Logic

     The Vaughan-Russell  [1982]  study,  the  most  ambitious   and  detailed
application  of a  recreation participation model to date,  focused on the recrea-
tional fishing benefits  that arise from  a change in  water  quality.   It  used  the
fact that more "desirable"  freshwater sport fish--coldwater and certain warm-
water  species—require better  water  quality.   Improved water  quality  may
alter the types of fish that can be supported in a  water  body.  Assuming  the
supporting  recreation  facilities are  available,  Vaughan-Russell   suggest  that
there will be a change in  the type of fish  (and perhaps  a net increase in  the
level of  fishing participation) from less desirable to the more desirable varie-
ties.  The sources of benefits from the water quality change arise from:

          The change in the composition of fishing activities

          Any net increase in the level of .participation {in fishing.

     to  implement this logic on  a  national scale,  the Vaughan-Russell  objec-
tive, requires the following:

          Measuring  the availability of  freshwater bodies for fishing  and
          their water qualities at a geographically disaggregated level.

          Modeling and measuring the  influence of  water quality  on par-
          ticipation  in  recreational fishing and on fishing .activities  by
          type of fish sought.

          Measuring  the economic benefits  according  to the  type  of fish
          sought.
     *This study is taken from Vaughan and Russell  [1982].
                                     3-22

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
This  review highlights some of the key elements  in this application of partici-
pation models.

Approach

     The first  step in the  analysis  was  to  estimate  the available  "fishable"
waters.   Using  dissolved oxygen  and  suspended solids criteria,  Vaughan-
Russell  projected  total fishable  water  on a  pre- and post-policy basis. - For
each policy scenario, they used the following steps:

     1.   Calculate the percentage increase from baseline levels of total
          fishable water as  represented in the RFF water quality network
          model.

     2.   Estimate the  policy impact by applying  the  improvement factors
          from  Item 1  above to a  national baseline of fishable acres per
          capita.

     3.   Estimate  the change  in composition  of fishing  activities  by
          using  the water  quality network  model to  calculate  fishable
          water by species type.

These  steps  are  based  on  a  recreational  fishing  participation model that
divides a person's participation choices into three decisions:

     1.   "Decide whether or not to fish"

     2.   "Decide what to fish for"

     3.   "Decide on a level of participation."

     The model implies that the amount of fishable water available affects the
probability  of  an  individual's  being  a fisherman.   Then,  the  suitability of
water  quality to  support  a  class  of fish  (e.g.,   coldwater,  warmwater,  game,
and  rough)  affects  the  type and  level of  fishing  activity.   Policies that
change water quality affect the availability of each type of fishable water.  In
the   Vaughn-Russell   study,  this  relationship   established   the  necessary
technical linkage between water quality and behavior (see Chapter  1).

     The empirical  analysis  of participation  was   based  on  the 1975  National
Survey  of  Hunting, Fishing,  and  Wildlife  Associated Recreation.   For Parts
(1) and (2)  of the fishing decision,  probability  models  were estimated using
several  statistical techniques.  The  models  included  a  wide  array of  socio-
economic variables  (e.g., age,  sex, income,  region,  residency in metropolitan
area,  residency in State with  coastline, and  total acres of fishable water in
the State  per capita).  The  estimated effect of   acres  of fishable  water per
capita on  the likelihood of  participation in  fishing was  positive and  statisti-
cally significant.
                                                     U.S. EPA Headquarters Library
                                                           Mail code 3201
                                    3-23              1200 Pennsylvania Avenue NW
                                                       Washington DC 20460

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
     Several methods were considered  for estimating the second-stage proba-
 bility  models--!.e., for the particular  type  of fishing selected.  The final set
 of  models  for  these  probabilities  was  based  on three  overlapping fishing
 choices--some trout,  some bass,  and  some .-rough fish.   The  most significant
 effect  of the fishery-specific water quality  variable .was the coldwater game-
 fish category.   Nonetheless,  the  signs of 'the  effects  of the  water quality
 variables generally  agree  with a^ priori expectations  for  all  categories  of
 fishing.

     In  the  last component  of  the model, the  number of days  spent  fishing in
 each category  were estimated.   The participation model requires  the  use  of all
 three  components to evaluate  the implications  of a change in water quality on
 the types of fishing  chosen.   Table 3-8 illustrates  the  results  of one of the
 Vaughan-Russell scenarios—adoption of  Best Practicable  Technology (BPT) for
 the predicted  changes  in the  mix  of  fishing .activities undertaken.   The  last
 three  lines  in  Table 3-8 provide the "bottom line" implications of the model in
 physical terms.  They are not benefit estimates  but,  rather,  increases in the
 number  of fishing  days of various types.  If benefit  estimates are  to be de-
 rived from the model, these fishing days must be valued.
             Table 3-8.   Vaughan-Russell Model--Predicted Effects
                     of BPT Regulations on Participation
      Change from base case
Change in  relevant variable  BPT/BASE"
Probability of being a fisherman

Probability of doing some:

     Trout fishing
     Bass fishing
     Rough fishing

Days  per capita per year:

     Trout
     Bass
     Rough

Total  days per year:

     Trout
     Bass
     Rough
            +0.0001'
            +0.0076
            -0.0142
            -0.0039
            +0.02
            +0.34
            +0.51
            +7-2 x 106
            -1.3 x 106
            +5.6 x 106
SOURCE:  Vaughan and Russell [1982], Table 6-1.   '

aThe  logit estimates using  a  sample size of 5,000 were  used for these esti-
 mates .

 This  may  seem an  inconsequential  change  in  the  probability of  being a
 fisherman,  but it implies an>increase of 20,000 fishermen per year.
                                     3-24

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 Benefit Estimation

     To value these fishing  days, Vaughan-Russell  conducted a separate sur-
 vey of fee fisheries in the United States and  used the  results of the survey
 to  estimate a  travel  cost  model,  accounting for  the  effects  of  a number of
 characteristics  of  the individual  fisheries.*  Separate models  were estimated
 for  trout  and catfish  (as  a  basis for  valuing  the rough  fishing).  The esti-
 mates  of consumer surplus  were  converted  to a per  day  per person  basis.
 Considering the differential  in these  values  between  trout  and  catfish,  the
 estimates  ranged  from $1.77 to $8.06  in the  final models.   These estimates
 provided the  basis for valuing the increments to fishing days projected  in the
 participation  model.   When the relevant daily  per capita  consumer surplus is
 applied  to  the  estimated increments  in  fishing days,  the incremental  benefits
 can be calculated from  the Vaughan-Russell model.

     One  of  the  most important  potential  limitations  to  the Vaughan-Russell
 methodology is  the procedure used to value fishing  days.   The relevant bene-
 fit  measure is the demand for fishing  as a recreational service flow,  not the
 measure estimated  from the demand model for a site's services.  While  there is
 a  correspondence  (see Anderson  [1974] or Carlton [1979]),  the  relationship
 between the two will  depend  on the nature of  the other  inputs to fishing  and
 the  activities  undertaken  at  the site.   Since the Vaughan-Russell  model relies
 on  a  very specific definition  of  the recreational activity and  treats  trips to
 the  fisheries  as single-day  visits, the  discrepancies may  not be great.  How-
 ever,  the transfer of the relationship between  travel cost  and participation
 models implied by their framework may not be possible in other applications.

     There should  be little  doubt,  even with  this cursory  review,  that the
 Vaughan-Russell model represents an- enormous  undertaking  and is  the best
 effort  available to  date  for  modeling  recreation participation.   The approach
 illustrated by this case study  could  be used in a  wide  variety of applications.
 For one example, see Chapter 6, Section 6.4.
Hedonic  Property Value Method

     Two types of recent models use market data on either property values or
real  wages along with quantitative measures of environmental amenities to esti-
mate individual  willingness to pay for a change in one or more amenities.  Re-"
searchers  have applied  both property  and wage models  to value  air quality
but have used only property value models in the case of water quality.

     These models,  known as hedonic  models,  use two assumptions:  (1) par-
ticipants in a market accurately perceive the characteristics of different  hous-
     *The  characteristics did not include water  quality because  the fisheries
were separated by the type of fish.
                                    3-25

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 ing  sites—including  water quality-and,  in  making  their  location decisions,
 will  consider them  along  with  the prices for  the  housing units;  and (2) there
 exists a continuous array of combinations of these characteristics across dif-
 ferent housing sites  within the  market.  An  ideal market process will  ensure
 that equilibrium housing  prices  and rents will  reflect the marginal valuations
 of the characteristics.

 Data Needs, Key Assumptions/Limitations,  and Features

     Only  a checklist on  data  needs,  key assumptions,  and  features  is  pre-
 sented  because the  resources  required to use this method would  exceed those
 available in  most States.   A detailed  discussion  and a  related case study will
 be presented in Volume  II.

 Data Needs:

          Property  values  (preferrably sale  price)  for  residential sites
          around water bodies with different water  qualities  in the same
          housing market.

          Information on other  site and neighborhood characteristics that
          may  affect property values.

          .Information on   individuals'  perceptions of  water  quality and
          relationship to available physical measures of water quality.

 Key  Assumptions/Limitations and Features:

          Market equilibrium

          Full  knowledge of the implications and effects of water quality

          Ability to determine extent of market and  specify relationships
          for hedonic price and demand functions

          Full  adjustment and ease of mobility.

 Damage Function Method

     The  damage function  method applied to valuing the benefits from  water
quality  improvement  is most relevant for the  effects of water quality on  human
health.   In  principle, this  approach examines all  the possible physical effects
of each type of  emission into a  water  body.  However, usually only the health
effects are considered.

     To use this approach  it is necessary to estimate,  for each class of effect
(i.e.,  chronic  versus acute), health  impacts that stem from the  relationship
between  the physical effect and the concentration of the relevant water pol-
lutant,  as  well  as any  other  factors  that  might  influence the  pollutant's
impact.   These  relationships  are  the  damage functions.   They  are  used  to
estimate the  physical  effects of specified changes  in water quality as measured
                                      3-26

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 by the concentrations of each of the individual  pollutants.   The method does
 not  provide a way  to value the physical effects  so that independent estimates
 of the health benefits must be developed.

 Data Needs, Key Assumptions/Limitations, and  Features

      The following  checklist  outlines  the data needs for the  damage function
 method, along with  its key assumptions  and features.   A detailed  case study
 will  be presented in Volume  II.

 Data Needs:

          Measures  of concentration of relevant  pollutants  in  water used
          by population over time and over .the geographic location.

          Measures  of features of population  and health patterns.

          Measures  of other  exogenous  factors that may  also  affect ob-
          served health patterns of population.

 Key Assumptions/Limitations and Features:

          Provides  largely statistical summaries of data on existing  popu-
          lation experiences.

          Assumes  no behavioral  substitition  on the part of  populations
          in response to  levels of each pollutant.                  :

          Produces  results  sensitive to the  statistical procedures used to
          estimate the models.

          Maintains   the  primary   advantage  allowing  classification  of
          effects according to physical impacts.

3.5  BUSINESS BENEFITS

     Benefits from  the water  quality programs can accrue  to  firms as well as
to households  because  many  provide for a  wide spectrum of uses for rivers
and  streams,  including industrial/commercial, agricultural,   navigation,  and
municipal water  supply  uses.  Measurement  of  business  benefits  are often
easier because market prices are usually available to value these benefits.

Theory:  The  Supply Function*

     In addition  to  the demand  function, discussed earlier,  economics provides
a second organizational guidepost for measuring benefits—the supply function,
     *This  discussion  is  a summary  of  the discussion  in Just,  Hueth, and
Schmitz [1982]/Chapter 4.
                                     3-27

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
 shown in Figure 3-5.  The supply curve shows the maximum quantity of out-
 put of good  X the  firm  is  willing to supply  at each  relevant  price.  If the
 market establishes the price at P ,  the firm  will produce the quantity  Q .
 The upward slope of the  curve in Tigure 3-5 indicates that the  firm is willing
 to  sell  more at higher prices than at  lower  prices, assuming  that factors in-
 fluencing the  supply  function—the prices of inputs,  such  as labor, energy,
 machinery,  and technological  improvements—do not change.
                 Price
                 $/X
                                                     Quantity X
                                                       time
                Figure 3-5. Supply function and the producer surplus.
     The concept of  producer  surplus  is used as the general measure for a
change in the  welfare of a firm.  In Figure 3-5, producer surplus is shown
as an  area  equal  to the  area  above the supply curve and below the price  line
for the firm or industry.  Whether a producer  is better off can be determined
by  examining the change in producer  surplus.  Producer surplus provides a
measure of a change in welfare  for a  firm because  its  welfare  is measured
directly in  dollars of cost  savings.  This view of a firm  is a simplified model
that does not include important differences  among firms or the distribution of
profits among owners and resource suppliers.

Practice:  Cost  Savings Method for Measuring Business  .Benefits

     The estimation of a  firm's benefits from water quality has been much  less
sophisticated  than the estimation  of household benefits.  The primary focus
has  been on estimation  of  the cost savings  associated  with  the water quality
change.  The estimates  are  derived largely from engineering cost  estimates.
In principle,  economic cost functions could  provide the  basis for  these esti-
mates, but, in practice, they have not.

     The hypothetical example  for business  benefits is for irrigation,  but  the
same method could  be adapted to the other situations.  The incremental pro-
ducer benefits that might arise from water quality programs are:
                                   3-28

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
      •    Reductions  in  industrial cost—firms using water in  processes
          may have  reduced  production  costs because either  less treat-
          ment  of water is  required or less maintenance is required for
          pumps, pipes,  and other parts of the production process.

          Reductions  in  agricultural  costs—farmers  using  water for  irri-
          gation may  have  reduced  production costs because less mainte-
          nance  of irrigation  equipment is required or less fertilizer per
          bushel of crop  is needed.

          Reductions  in  navigation costs—barges and  other water trans-
          port  conveyances  may  have  reduced  risk  of  accident.   Ship
          maintenance may be reduced.

      From .these  simple  examples two  major  points arise.   The  first is
that  the  focus  on incremental benefits  of  water  quality  decisions  will
mean these benefits are  considerably smaller than they  would be if meas-
uring the total  benefits  of  all water regulations  were the primary objec-
tive  of the  benefit-cost assessment.  That  is, the  baseline is  important
in .measuring the benefits of  a particular decision.  The second  point Is
that the relative orders of  magnitude of these benefits will be very speci-
fic to the Individual  water bodies evaluated.  For example, the  comple-
mentary attributes necessary for  recreation,  such  as  access  and overall
surroundings, might  be  at  very low levels  in some instances,  while the
potential  for  producer benefits from other designated uses is very large.
This  point emphasizes the  importance of the focus  in .the proposed water
quality  standards program on selecting  key segments and considering  each
on a specific basis.

Data  Needs,  Key Assumptions/Limitations,  and Features

     The  following checklist outlines the data needs of the cost  savings
approach, along with  its key assumptions and features.

Data  Needs:

          Cost data for firm  (see Chapter 4 for details)

          Demand information such  as  market prices and responsiveness
          of  sales to price changes.

Key Assumptions/Limitations and Features:

          All  products and  inputs (labor, machines) are bought and  sold
          In  markets  that are perfectly competitive;  that is, no buyer or
          seller has influence over market prices.

          The supply  curve reflects  the marginal  social  cost of producing
          the product or  service.   This implies that neither  external
          costs  nor subsidies  are present in the market.  (This is  un-
          likely  for the  irrigation example  because of the various legal
          and regulatory influences  in  the market,  but it is a  useful  as-
          sumption to simplify exposition.)

                                 3-29

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
           A  shift  in  the supply of  a :producer's services will not  affect
           the price at which they are sold in the market.
 * .
                                                   *
                      CASE STUDY:   IRRIGATION. BENEFITS

      Suppose that a State is considering a change in the designated uses.of a
 river segment to provide for  fish and wildlife propagation.  As  a byproduct
 of this  use  designation,  the quality of water available  for  irrigation is as-
 sumed  to  improve,  thus  shifting  the supply of irrigation services—because
 more high-quality water is  available for irrigation—outward from  Sj to S2,  as
 shown  in  Figure  3-6.*   In  an  application,  the  practitioner may  have limited
 data on some costs,  but seldom enough  to estimate the entire  supply function.
 By  supplementing the available data (e.g.,  from the Bureau of Reclamation  or
 the U.S.  Department of Agriculture [USDA])  with assumptions based on  com-
 mon  sense,  a  rough  cut  at the problem can  be obtained.  For example  pur-
 poses, the entire supply curve is drawn.
            $/103 gat
                US
                o>
                1
                <*•»
                o

                I 1
                a.
  Change in
~ Producer Surplus
                                                           irrigation
                                                           services
                            100        200

                           Quantity of Irrigation Service


                        Figure 3-6.  Irrigation benefits.
                            300  103 gal/yr
     *The stream's flow is  assumed  to  be strong enough that the  increases in
irrigation will  not noticeably  reduce it.   Prior  to  the change in  use designa-
tion, the limiting factor is assumed to be water quality rather than flow.
                                      3-30

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     The task is to calculate the irrigation  benefits from this shift in supply--
the  change  in  producer surplus  attributed to the implementation of the new
designated  use.  The  crosshatched portions of Areas  a and  b in  Figure 3-6
are the two  components of  the  change in  producer surplus.  Area a is the new
producer surplus resulting from reduced cost of the original  volume of  irriga-
tion services (100).  Area b  is the  new  producer surplus on the additional
volume of irrigation  attributable to the reduced cost resulting from the water
quality standards.

     As drawn, Area  a is a  parallelogram showing  the cost  savings  on  the
original irrigation volume.  Using the formula for the area of a parallelogram:

     .Area a = (side)  x (perpendicular distance to parallel side)

     Area a = $(2-1) x  (100-0)

     Area a = $(1) x  (100)

     Area a - $100/year.

     Area b is  the additional irrigation induced by the decrease in costs due
to the  water quality standards.   Using the formula for the area of a triangle:

     Area b = ^(base) x (height)

     Area b = ^$(2-1) x  (300-100)

     Area b= %$(D * (200)

     Area b - $100/year.

     Thus,  the change in   producer  surplus—the measure of  firm benefits—
attributable  to  the  cost savings from  the  additional  river uses in the  water
quality standards is $200 a year.


     There  are several important  caveats  to the forgoing simple example  for
estimating firm benefits:

          The costs are not quite as simple as in this example.  However,
          the basic measurement concept still applies.

          The assumptions  required for the example are  stringent  ones,
          but they  do   provide  a workable  approximation for many indi-
          vidual river segments.

          In  the cases  of agriculture and nagivation,  institutional factors
          in  those markets may distort  the true social  cost.   For ex-
          ample, the subsidization  of  waterway activities  and the regu-
          lated  rates in  railway  and highway transportation  may violate
          the assumptions of perfect competition  in those markets.
                                 3-31

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
          If the  assumption of perfect competition  in the  input  markets
          does  not  hold,  the producer  surplus may actually  accrue to
          providers of labor or capital services.

          Market  power  resulting  in control over market prices and out-
          puts  will  distort  the  supply  relationships  and make prices
          higher than in competition.
3.6  PUBLIC WATER SUPPLY BENEFITS

     Reductions  in  treatment requirements for municipal  water supplies consti-
tute  another  potential   source  of  benefits  from   water  quality  program
decisions.   By  having a  use designation that provides  for  fish  and wildlife
propagation, a city that  uses a  river as a water supply  source may be able to
provide  water with  less  treatment  than  if  the  use designation were agricul-
tural or industrial.  Once again,  it is essential to remember  that the focus of
the  benefit measurement .should be the incremental benefits attributable to the
particular policy, not total benefits from all water regulations.

     Since calculation  of  these  benefits could proceed exactly as  in  the case
.of business .benefits, no  case study is provided.   The  same  key  assumptions
apply as with business  benefits.

     The critical issue of toxic substances  or  toxic  pollutants,  which  would
apply to a public water  supply, is  not considered in this  handbook.  As more
information  becomes available on  the  extent and  effects  of  toxics and their
relationships to  the  water quality regulations,  a change  in this focus may be
warranted.  This is an issue that bears  future scrutiny  because  of .potential
health benefits from reducing toxic pollutants.

3.7  SUMMARY

     This chapter has reviewed basic benefits  concepts  and the approaches
used to  measure them.   An individual's willingness to pay is  the centraKtenet
underlying all the methods discussed in this chapter.  Even though all assess-
ments may not require the  practitioner to  use measurement methods,  willing-
ness to  pay  provides an  organizing principle for  even qualitative  assessments
of benefits.

     Major points developed in the  chapter include:

          The  assessment  should  be  tailored to  balance  the complexity
          and importance of the policy action to the available resources.

     •     The change in consumer surplus should  be used as the meas-
          ure  of willingness to pay  for improvements  in the well-being of
          households.
                                 3-32

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
The travel  cost  method  can provide  willingness-to-pay-based
measures of water quality changes  under many conditions.   It
measures only  user  benefits  and is sensitive to the treatment
of  time  costs   and  substitute sites.   The  travel  cost  method
estimates demand for site services.

•The contingent valuation  survey method also provides wifling-
ness-to-pay-based measures  of  water  quality  changes  under
many conditions.  It can measure both  user  and intrinsic bene-
fits  and  is  sensitive to  questionnaire  design  and  administra-
tion.

The participation  survey  method provides measures of changes
in  level  of use—visitor  days—for  a   recreation  activity  and
often requires ad  hoc valuation of use to develop benefits.

Cost savings can provide estimates of  willingness-to-pay-based
measures (producer  surplus)  of  changes in the economic  well-
being of firms.
                         3-33

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                  CHAPTER 4

            MEASURING THE COSTS OF WATER  QUALITY PROGRAMS
 4.1   INTRODUCTION

      Why  is opportunity  cost  the basis for measuring  costs?  What types of
 approaches are  available  to measure  costs?  What practical problems arise in
 measuring costs?  Are there any examples of cost measurement?

      This  chapter  focuses on  determining the incremental costs of a  water
 quality program.   It defines various cost categories,  discusses their relation-
 ships,  and reviews  costing methods  relevant for  users  of this handbook.  It
 covers  costs for  both  industry and publicly owned treatment  works  (POTWs)
 and presents several case studies to  illustrate how the  general principles are
 applied.  Although  the examples  are  oriented  toward potential  water quality
 standards decisions, they  are.general enough for use.in other applications.

      Throughout  this  chapter,  opportunity costs—the value to  society  as  a
 whole of a  resource's  best alternative  use—provide the  measurement basis for
 costing in  a  benefit-cost  assessment.   Engineering and accounting  cost  esti-
 mates may  differ from opportunity costs because of  cost-sharing .mechanisms
 such  as taxes  and  subsidies.  In these cases,  the practitioner faces the dif-
 ficult task of determining the value of opportunity costs.

     This  chapter  suggests practical  approaches  to  costing  and  highlights
 some  of the more difficult issues,  which  will  get .more detailed  treatment in
 Volume  II.  Specifically, Section 4.2 presents the basics underlying the  meas-
 urement of  costs, and  Section 4.3 describes two general  approaches,  engineer-
 ing and econometric,  to  measuring costs.   Section  4.4-defines types of cost
 and major  cost  categories  to be used in an assessment.  Section  4.5  discusses
 the practical aspects of determining costs—including data, sources, the  use of
 indexes, and major  factors influencing cost estimates—and concludes with a
 sample  data form.   Section  4.6 describes the engineering methods for estimat-
 ing costs,  and  Section  4.7  provides examples  using the engineering methods.
 Section  4.8 offers some general cautions for measuring costs.  Finally, Section
 4.9 summarizes the chapter's major points.

 4.2  MEASURING COSTS:   THE BASIC  CONCEPTS

     This section reviews the fundamental  economic principle of cost:  oppor-
tunity cost, which  measures the  cost  of any  resource  in  terms  of its  next
 best alternative use.   That is, the  value of forgone alternative  uses for any
 resource provides the  basis for estimating the cost of  any  specific use of that
 resource.
                                      4-.1

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
      For a  water  quality  decision,  opportunity costs  include  both  explicit
 costs  (e.g., wages and  salaries, or  payments  for  materials and energy)  as
 well  as implicit  costs  (what self-owned  and  employed  resources could have
 earned in their best alternative  uses).  For example,  the implicit  cost of labor
 is the highest wage the owner could receive for his labor services.

      For firms  and households,  the opportunity  costs  are the private costs of
 a  regulatory  action.   If  the  action also negatively  affects others,  either
 households or firms,  additional  costs are  incurred—in technical terms,  exter-
 nal  costs.   In  a benefit-cost .assessment, the opportunity cost  to society is
 the relevant measure of cost, the sum of private and external costs.

     The economic  guideposts of  supply  and  demand functions   described  in
 Chapter 3 can be used to view the opportunity cost concept.  These functions
 are combined in  Figure 4-1,  which illustrates  a  market for good  X.  The de-
 mand  curve, D,  shows the amount demanders are willing  to buy  at each  of
 several  prices, while the  supply curve, S, reveals the amounts suppliers will
 provide at  various  prices.  Market forces'will cause the price to  settle  at P0,
 with the resulting quantity at  Q0.
                 Price
                 $/Ox
                                                       Deadweight
                                                         lots
                                           Q! QQ  Quantity/time


                    Figure 4-1. Measurement of opportunity/costs.
     One way  to  view the cost of a  regulatory action is  to suggest it will im-
pose costs on  firms,  resulting in a shift of the industry supply curve from S
to S1.   In this case,  the regulation  causes a shift in the curve by an amount
that recovers  the costs of compliance—shown  by the hatched area in Figure
4-1.  These  costs constitute one  element in the opportunity cost of the regu-
lation—the additional  opportunity costs (e.g.,  extra operation and mainte-
nance)  required to meet the regulatory standard.  The second element of op-
portunity cost  is  shown  by the  shaded triangle—the loss to society because
the produced  and purchased quantity  of  X is reduced  from Q0  to Qt when
supply  shifts.   In  technical terms,  some  producer and  consumer  surplus  is
lost (dead weight  loss).
                                      4-2

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
      In practice,  it is usually impossible to construct the supply curve for an
 industry.   Instead,  the practitioner  can use  the available  cost  information,
 often  for an  "ideal"  plant,  and  assume the  supply  curve  is horizontal,   in
 most cases/  the loss  in accuracy caused by making this assumption  is not  a
 severe  limitation because the  estimated  compliance costs,  the largest compo-
 nent of opportunity - cost,  are  less  affected  than  the dead weight  loss  to
 society.

      Under  most circumstances, market prices of goods and services provide  a
 good estimate  of their  social opportunity  costs.   However,  in  some cases,
 there  can be  significant differences between market price and  social cost.  As
 .noted  in  Chapter 2, the most significant case relevant to water quality pro-
 grams  is  the difference between social and  private rates of  return on capital
 due to corporate  income taxation.    In  addition,  subsidies   and  grants  may
 cause the financial costs to participants to differ from social costs.

 4.3 MEASURING COSTS:  TWO GENERAL APPROACHES

      Evaluating the  costs  of  regulatory actions requires the collection  and
 analysis  of  relevant industry  and municipal  cost  data.  A thorough accounting
 of  costs for  potentially affected  firms and  cities is desirable.   There are two
 main approaches to estimate  these costs:  econometric cost estimation and engi-
 neering cost estimation.

     Econometric cost estimation, sometimes referred to  as the statistical  ap-
 proach,  uses  cost-output relationships that are  identifiable through  empirical
 testing.   Sometimes,  statistical  cost estimation offers  a way  to determine the
 costs of proposed alternatives.   It is possible that data can  be gathered for
 actual  firms,  most of  which  have identifiably different  production processes
 and some  of which already meet regulatory alternatives of the type  under con-
 sideration.  Given  sufficient  data, production  relationships  representative of
 complying and  noncomplying  firms can be  estimated.   Then,  if the prices of
 labor and equipment are known,  it is possible to establish cost-output relation-
 ships  known as cost functions.  These cost functions,  in turn, can be  used
 to evaluate the  cost of regulatory alternatives.

     Unfortunately,  empirical  studies  of  this  type  are rarely practicable for
 regulatory analyses.   The major difficulty  usually  is  that sufficient technical
 data are .not available.  In particular,  published data are usually  scarce,  and
 potentially useful  data,  available only   from  firms,  are typically  considered
 proprietary.

     The  second approach to cost estimation is  the  engineering cost approach.
 This approach  offers a  viable alternative to statistical  cost estimation  because
 it does not  rely on the availability of  a firm's actual  data.  Rather,  engineers
 familiar  with  relevant industrial  processes use a wide variety  of information to
 establish  relationships  between  inputs,  outputs, and costs.   These  relation-
 ships are  presented for hypothetical  facilities both with and  without proposed
 regulatory controls.   The  practitioner  uses  the facility data  to determine  the
costs of  the  regulatory alternatives.  This general approach is the  focus of
this chapter.
                                       4-3

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
4.4  TYPES OF COSTS

     This  section  defines  the  major categories  that  can be used  in  assessing
costs.  The basic types of cost are  capital  costs,  operating  and maintenance
costs,  reinvestment,  and  salvage costs.  The discussion is  oriented toward
the  incremental  costs  of a regulatory  action  that  affects  water quality.   In
many  situations,  this  orientation  will  mean  upgrading an  existing facility
rather than constructing a  new facility.

     Incremental costs may include both additional end-of-pipe treatment units
and  modification of  existing  production or  treatment  units.  Most documents
relating to treatment costs are concerned  with the former because the set of
unit treatment processes is fairly  well  defined,  allowing  cost estimation  to be
more standardized.  Changes in production  processes  (or manufacturing)  are
more difficult to  analyze and are not discussed.

Capital Costs

     Capital costs  (K)  represent  initial  costs associated with  the construction
or upgrading  of a facility to meet the treatment  requirements plus periodic
reinvestments  as  individual  components  wear  out and must  be  replaced.
Table 4-1  shows the kinds of  costs that should be  included  in a  capital cost
estimate.   They  are divided  into  three main categories: component installed
construction  costs,  noncomponent construction  costs,   and  nonconstruction
costs.   The first  category includes physical treatment units  (e.g.,  activated
carbon,  chemically assisted clarification)  and  miscellaneous  structures.   The
second  category  includes  construction  items  not  necessarily associated  with
individual  structures,  such  as site preparation.  The last category includes
all the miscellaneous costs  in addition to construction costs,  including contrac-
tor  fees and interest  payments.   Care must be taken to identify  incremental
costs associated  with the particular water quality decisions.   For example, up-
grades  of  existing facilities may  not  require  any  additional  or miscellaneous
structures.

     In  addition  to  initial  capital  costs,  replacement costs  or reinvestment
costs are  required over the life of the  project as  individual  pieces  of equip-
ment reach the  end  of their  useful  life.   Although the  line between replace-
ment and  repair  can  be  a fuzzy one,  the  definition  is  quite operational.
Items that  are depreciated  over a number of  years rather than expensed imme-
diately  as  costs are considered to be capital items and  are treated as reinvest-
ment.

     In most  cases,  no  adjustment is required  to  use .engineering cost esti-
mates as measures of social cost as long as  they are based on  market prices.
This  includes  the  proper  allocation of interest and contractor's fees.   Some
caution is  required  in  dealing with reinvestment because the available meas-
ures  are  based  on  what tax  laws allow  and  not on  the actual  social  cost.
Volume  II will cover this in  more detail.
                                    4-4

-------
1
1




Table 4-1 . Components of Capital and Operation and Maintenance Costs
1












1



1




















A. Capital Costs
(1) . Component installed construction costs
unit processes
miscellaneous structures
(2) Noncomponent construction costs
site preparation
piping
electrical
instrumentation
(3) Nbnconstruction costs
land costs
engineering and construction supervision
contingencies
.administrative and legal
miscellaneous nonconstruction labor (testing, etc.
design
fees
interest during construction
B. Operation and Maintenance Costs
.
(1) Variable operating costs
• labor
materials
chemical
energy

(2) Byproduct, other credits
(3) Overhead items

insurance
taxes
administrative and other allocations


Operation and Maintenance Costs
:
Operation and maintenance (O&M) costs represent the annual
running and maintaining the facility after its construction (see Table
are divided into three groups: variable operating costs (labor,
energy, etc.)/ byproduct and other credits, and overhead items.














.)




















costs of
4-1) and
materials,
Control
efforts resulting from in-plant process changes may also affect revenues or
1
1

1
production costs; these are included in the byproduct credits.

4-5






-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     To be  consistent  with  the definition of incremental  costs,  the overhead
 items  should include only the  additions  required  by  the project,  not a pro
 rata allocation  based on  overall costs.   The  treatment  of taxes  in  a benefit-
 cost assessment raises  some  questions.  Although taxes  are not costs from the
 point  of  view of the  nation  as a whole, tax receipts  that  leave a  particular
 State  may be regarded by that State as a real cost in  its benefit-cost assess-
 ment.   State and  local taxes  should not  be counted  as  social  costs  in  any
 case; they are simply transfers.

     Annual O&M costs may  vary over  the life of  the  facility.   For example,
 growth in population or water use will increase the flow to a POTW  over time,
 causing  O&M costs  to  increase.  If the growth rate is high, using the first
 year's O&M  costs  may  significantly  underestimate  average  annual  O&M costs
 over the life of the project.

 Reinvestment Costs

     Reinvestment  costs  (RC)  represent  periodic  replacements  of  individual
 units  whose lifetime  is  shorter than that of the overall  project. ; Depending on
 data  availability,  it may  be more convenient  to  represent  this  process as
 either the  replacement  of particular  units  at discrete  intervals  or  as a con-
 stant fraction of initial investment costs each year.  Table 4-2 shows the for-
 mula  for  each.   If  the first approach  is  used, capital costs may  be  broken
 down  into groups  with different  average ages and the formula  applied sepa-
 rately to each group  using the lifetime applicable to that  group.

 Salvage Value

     Salvage value (SV) is the market  value of the  facility at the end of the
 planning  period.  A  wide range of  values  is  possible depending  both on what
 that alternative  use  is and  on what assumption is  made about reinvestment
 (see the  previous  subsection).  One extreme case is that the facility is  ex-
 pected  to  continue operating beyond the  end of  the  planning  period in the
 same fashion as  before.  In  that  case,  the salvage value depends on the  ini-
 tial investment  cost  and  the remaining  useful life  after the  planning period.
 If the reinvestment  process  is best characterized as  a  series of  periodic rein-
 vestments,  the  value of the facility is  proportional to  the ratio  of  its useful
 life at  the end of the  planning period and its total useful  life.

    - If the  reinvestment process is better represented as an average reinvest-
 ment  of amount  dK  each  year  (see Table  4-2), the expected lifetime of the
facility has no end as  long as the annual  reinvestments  are made.  Therefore,
the salvage value at the end of the planning  period is  still K  if the facility is
expected to continue  in the same use as before.

     If the facility  is   not expected to  continue in its  present  use  after the
 planning period, its  scrap value must be determined.  Any permanent fixtures
                                    4-6

-------
1
1
1



1

1




1








1
•
1

1

1

1

1
•
Table 4-2. Variables and Definitions for Measuring Costs


1.

2.
3.
4.
5.
6.

7.

8.
9.

10.

11.
12.


13.


14.
15.
16.

17.

18.

Variable
Planning period

Real social discount rate
Investment costs
O&M costs
Investment lifetime
Physical depreciation rate

Number of replacements in
planning period
Growth rate of O&M costs
Reinvestment costs

Fraction of salvageable value

Salvage value
Present value of stream of
payments for N years at
discount rate s
Present value of rein-
vestment costs

Present value of salvage
Present value of O&M costs
Present value of all
capital costs
Present value of all
project costs
Total annual cost of project
aFirst definition in the right-hand
ments, where RC = K; the second

Symbol
N

s
K
OM
L
d

M

9
RC

q

SV
PV(N,s


PVRC


PVSV
PVOM
PVK

TPV

TAG

Source
Parameters

Parameters
Project costs
Project costs
Project costs
Project costs

Greatest integer N/L

Parameter
K every L years; or
dK every year
Project costs

qK
) (1-(1+s)"N)/s


RC I (1+s)~J ; or
j=1
RC-PV(N,s)
SV(1+s)~N
OM-PV(N,s)
K + PVRC - PVSV

PVK + PVOM

TPV/PV(N,s)
column represents periodic reinvest-
definition
represents annual reinvest-
ments, where RC = dK.
1

1







4-7





-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
such  as concrete tanks  or structures are  likely  to  have ho salvage value.*
Machinery  and  equipment  items may  have  25 to 50  percent of their original
value.  Cash or  natural  resources  on hand  can  be valued at 100 percent of
current value,  and  other current assets  may .be  valued at 70 to  100 percent
of their current value,  depending on their salability.

Summary Cost Measures

     Discounting  allows the four  types of costs to  be combined to obtain a
single overall  cost  estimate for a project.   Based on the  discussion given in
Chapter 2,  the use of the discount  rate is summarized  below.   Specifically/
discount rates are  used  to  construct  two  kinds of summary measures:  pres-
ent  value  (PV),  where  O&M  costs  are  capitalized,  and total  annual costs
(TAG),  where  capital  costs   are  annualized.   Table  4-2 shows these  two
methods along with  the variables  used to  develop  measures of  social  cost.  In
addition,  Table 4-2 summarizes the formulas for the components  of the total
present value of the costs of a  project.

     The  present value  of  all capital  and O&M costs  (TPV)  is  obtained  by
adding  the  present values of  the cost components (salvage value is  sub-
tracted ):
                      TPV = K  + PVRC -  PVSV + PVOM
(4.1)
     The total annual  cost  (TAG)  of  the  project is a constant amount whose
present  discounted  sum over the project period is  equal to the present value
of  project  costs  TPV.   By the  definition  of  the present value  factor (PV)
given in Table 4-2,
                            TAG = TPV/PV(N,s)


4.5  PRACTICAL ISSUES IN MEASURING COSTS
(4.2)
     This  section  discusses  the  practical  aspects of  measuring costs.   It
covers sources  of data,  the  use of  cost  indexes,  and major factors  affecting
cost estimates.   A  sample data form,  one method  of organizing  the costing
process, concludes the section.

Sources of Cost Data

     There  are  three commonly used  sources of cost data:   vendor informa-
tion,  estimating manuals,  and industry information.   In  the past, many prac-
     *Firms can write off such assets as tax losses.  However, these writeoffs
are not appropriate for measuring  social  costs  because society  still bears the
full cost of the resources.  The distribution  of who in society  bears the cost
is different.  Taxpayers and  the firm bear the costs when they are written
off,  and the firm and  consumers of its  product bear the cost  when they are
not written off.
                                   4-8

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
titioners  have been  successful  in obtaining cost estimates for both installed
capital  costs  and annual operating costs  from equipment vendors.  These esti-
mates  are generally solicited in writing  along with operating features of the
model plants for which cost estimates are needed.

     Estimating manuals have also  been  useful in  developing  cost  estimates.
Two popular  manuals are published by Richardson  Engineering Services, Inc.
[1977] -and R. S. Means Company, Inc. [1981].  Richardson's manual is  useful
in  preparing  cost  estimates  for process  industries,  and  Means'  manual  is
geared  to  the construction  industry.  Both  manuals are  written  to provide
costs for  individual  components rather  than total  systems and  thus require
some skill and care  in  their use.  Estimates can  also be obtained  by the use
of  cost factors.   In this procedure,  major equipment costs are multiplied  by
appropriate factors  to  estimate  other  cost  elements.  The factors  are derived
from experience  with previous plant construction  costs.  Some  procedures use
a  single factor to estimate total  capital investment,  but greater accuracy can
be achieved from a  method  such  as  Guthrie's [1974],  which separates  labor
and material costs and applies individual factors to  each major process item.

     Information  supplied by the controlled industry may be useful in estimat-
ing  costs.  If plants can be identified that are already controlled to the level
under  investigation,  both total  installed  costs  and  annual operating costs can
be obtained from this source.   Obtaining estimates  of each cost  element from
more than one source is  a way to validate estimates.

The Use of Cost Indexes

     Treatment cost  indexes allow cost  estimates from  different  years  to  be
converted  to  dollars of a single year to yield a valid  comparison.   Costs of
various components  included  in  both  capital  and  O&M costs change over time
due both to  overall  changes  in  the  price  level (inflation)  and to changes in
relative  prices.   The  problem  of forecasting  general  price inflation can  be
avoided  by expressing   all  costs  in  constant dollars  of  a  given year,  but
changes in  relative  prices still  need to be predicted.  Unless  there  are com-
pelling  reasons to do otherwise, it  is  simplest and  reasonably  safe  to assume
constant  real  costs  in  future  years.  Of course,  this assumption  must  be
applied  to all  components  of the benefit-cost assessment  to ensure consist-
ency.

     Cost  indexes are  usually represented as  a  number showing the ratio of
the  cost of a unit in dollars of  a  given  year  to  the cost of the same unit in
dollars  of the  base  year multiplied by 100.  In adjusting  these costs to con-
stant dollars  in  a  given  year, the  practitioner must take  account of the
change  in  the index  and  the  overall change in the  price level.  For  example,
if  the  cost of  a treatment plant is  given for 1975 in current  (i.e.,  1975)
dollars and  must be converted to 1977 costs in  1977  dollars,  the U.S.  Environ-
mental   Protection Agency's  (EPA)  Sewage Treatment Plant  Construction Cost
(STPCC) Index [Michel]  can be used as follows:
                                    4-9

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     .Cost (77)  =  Cost (75)
                =  Cost (75)  x
STPCC  (77)
STPCC  (75)

278.3
250.0
                =  Cost (75)  x  1.11  .


 If  the  costs for a given year  are  to  be  expressed in  the constant  dollars of
 another year,  then the  gross national  product  (GNP)  deflator or  another
 general price  index  must be used.  For  example,  costs shown above for 1977
 may  need  to  be converted to 1976  current dollars.  Using the convention that
 PGNP (N) is the GNP deflator* in year  N  and that the notation cost (m,  n)
 refers  to  costs corresponding  to year m  expressed  in constant dollars of year
 n gives:
      Cost (77, 76)  =  Cost (77,  77)
                    =  Cost (77,  77)
        PGNP (76)
        PGNP  (77)

        1.321
        1.398
                    =  Cost (77,  77)  x  0.945 .


      Cost indexes  are available for both capital and O&M costs.  One index to
 use  for  O&M  costs  is  the  U.S.  Environmental Protection  Agency's  (EPA)
 Municipal  Wastewater  Treatment  Plant Operation and  Maintenance Cost Index
 [Michel].  This index  is a weighted average of cost indexes for labor, chemi-
 cals,  power,  maintenance,  other costs,  and  a  "quality added"  factor.   Al-
 though developed  primarily for secondary treatment plants, the mix of inputs
 for O&M costs of advanced treatment plants should not differ much.

      Several  construction  cost   indexes  are  available  for adjusting capital
 costs.   These  include EPA's  STPCC  index  used  earlier,  the  Engineering
 New-Record  Cost  Index  (ENR),t and  the  Chemical  Engineering  Plant Con-
 struction Cost  Index  (CE).f  The nature  of the treatment system being exa-
 mined determines  which  of these indexes is most suitable to use.  'Both  the
 STPCC  and   ENR  indexes  are  more oriented to secondary treatment plants,
.where large  concrete  tanks play  an  important role, but  they  are  also appro-
     *The GNP  deflator is published by the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis.
 The wholesale price  index  (WPI),  another useful  index,  appears in the U.S.
 Bureau of Labor Statistics,  Producer^ Pnces and Price Indexes.

     tAppears weekly  in the Engineering News-Record,  published by McGraw
 Hill.

     ^Appears in Chemical Engineering, published by McGraw Hill.
                                   4-10

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 priate  for  some  advanced  treatment  (AT)  processes  (such  as  chemically
 assisted  clarification),  which  rely  on  large tanks.   The  CE  index is more
 suitable for  processes  where  equipment plays a  large role in costs, such as
 use of  activated  carbon.   However,  it  is  difficult  to  make  hard and  fast
 rules.  The cumulative percent increases of the  STPCC  and  ENR indexes are
 close, while that of the GE index is somewhat lower.

     To arrive at a cost figure more accurate than  one that results from the
 use of the  national average indexes alone, locality factors can be  applied to
 an  estimated cost or cost index.  The use of locality factors,  which  have been
 calculated from generally available  statistics,  permits  the localizing of national
 average cost  data  on various cost items.   Locality factors are available from
 the U.S.  Environmental  Protection  Agency's  (EPA)  Sewage  Treatment  Plant
 and Sewer Construction Cost Index [Michel].

 Major  Factors  Affecting Cost Estimates

     The cost of a treatment  process is influenced by a multitude of factors.
 Among the important ones are wastewater  flow  rate,  pollutant loadings,  plant
 location,  and  performance  (i.e.,  amount  of pollutant  removed and effluent
 concentrations).  Most  treatment  technologies  show economies of scale;  i.e.,
 costs  increase at a slower rate than flow size.   Thus,  the cost per gallon of
 wastewater treated  in a large plant is less  than that treated in a smaller plant
 that meets the same treatment performance criteria.   In general, the  scaling
 factor*  varies  with size of  flow  and technology.   For  preliminary planning-
 purposes, the following  values are- useful for extrapolating the treatment cost
 of a given treatment plant size to others:

                    Cost  Item           Scaling Factor

                    Capital              0.6 to 0.9

                    O&M                0.7 to 0.9
                    Labor              0.5 to 0.7
                    Utilities and         1.0
                      chemicals

 The upper end of the range for the scaling  factors (implying less economy of
 scale than the lower end) is  associated with the more advanced treatment tech-
 nologies,  such as  carbon adsorption and electrolysis, to which this  handbook
 is  oriented.   Economies   of  scale- also appear in the  relationship  of cost to
 waste loading but are less prevalent than in the cost-to-flow-size relationship.
     *As used here, scaling factor refers to x In the following equation:
where  Cj is a cost for a  treatment  plant with flow Qj and  C2 is the estimated
cost for a plant with flow Q2.
                                   4-77

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
      Because wastewater  flows  and  loadings  tend  to  show greater  variability
 in a  POTW than they do in an industrial plant,  equalization  is commonly used
 to smooth out fluctuations.  Even  so,  the POTW customarily is designed with
 some excess capacity to accommodate variations in  flow and waste loading.

      In  some cases,  more  intensive treatment effort  in the  treatment plant—
 such as additional chemicals or  energy input—can result in enhanced perform-
 ance or  accommodation of  a greater volume of wastewater without  sacrificing
 design  performance.   However,  the incremental cost usually  is  high.  There-
 fore, .it  is  less costly in  the  long  run to upgrade or expand the treatment
 facility if actual flow,  loading, or  performance is  expected to change appre-
 ciably from initial design conditions.

      It is  generally more costly to upgrade an  existing  plant by retrofitting
 than  it is to use the  same treatment train  in  a  new  plant.  The treatment in
 place at  a  plant may limit the choice of higher treatment  technologies that can
 be  selected to upgrade  the  plant.  Upgrading  usually requires  engineering
 effort,  rewiring,  and  additional piping at the existing facility.   The additional
 cost  attributed to retrofitting  a plant  is  sensitive to the specific features of
 the  plant and  the  site,  so these  factors should be considered in  developing
 retrofit .cost factors.  Based on limited observations, costs of retrofitting  an
 existing plant can range  from 1 .to 15 percent higher than the cost of  incor-
 porating  the same treatment train  in  the initial  design of a  new plant  [U.S.
 EPA, 1976].  The  added  cost of retrofit  in  percentage terms  is inversely pro-
 portional  to the capacity of the treatment facility.

 Sample  Data Form

     A  "model  plant  form" can be used to compile parametric and  cost esti-
 mates  in  an orderly fashion.  The  form can be continually revised to meet the
 needs of  the  specific  data requirements  of an assessment.  A model  plant
 questionnaire of this  type is applicable  only for regulatory  alternatives that
 involve engineering  controls.   Figure 4-2  presents a version  of  the  model
 plant questionnaire.

 4.6  COST  ESTIMATING TECHNIQUES

     This  section  on  cost estimating  techniques  defines  the components  of
treatment systems  and describes several  variations  on the basic costing  tech-
 niques.   Finally,  the  question  of  how to  proceed  when  no  directly relevant
cost sources  are  available  is discussed.  The techniques described here are
appropriate for  costing both POTWs and industrial dischargers.

Components of Treatment  Systems

     To  analyze the  costs  of  a particular  proposed  treatment  system,   it is
useful to  break it down into its components.  Although each  treatment system
has its unique  aspects, the individual  components  are more  standardized and
hence more easily costed  using  standard references,  where costs  are defined
in terms  of a few  major parameters. The detail of the breakdown  depends on
the accuracy of the estimate required.  It is useful to understand the relation-
ships of the following three levels of treatment units:


                                    4-12

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                      MODEL PLANT FORM
 1. Model Ham Number and Description
   Number  	
   Description
 2. If new, ran design tif* (yeari)
   If existing, itata plant age (yean)
   and remaining life (yean)	
 3. Legal Depreciation Period (yean) and Usual Depreciation Method
   Plant 	
   Compliance Equipment
4. Discuss what relationship exirti, if any, between existing plant age and model type. Discuss age distribution of exist-
   ing plants.
                                                Alternative 1
                                                 (Baseline)
                                                                     Alternative 2
                                                                                       Alternative n
5. Product Names, Annual Capacity Outputs

   Primary Product

   Name 	

   Annual Physical Output Capacity
   Units Specified 	
   Producer Price, 19_
   per unit	
                     .dollars
   Secondary Product

   Name 	
   Annual Physical Output Capacity
   Units Specif ied 	
   Producer Price, 19	dollars
   per unit  	
   Marketable Byproduct

   Name	
   Annual Physical Output Capacity
   Units Specified 	
8. Annual In-Plant Consumption of any of the
   Products Lilted in (5L

   Name 	
   Quantity

   Name 	'
   Quantity

7. Installed Capital Cost 19	dollars
   OF NEW PLANT

8. Installed Capital Cost of Compliance
   Equipment for Existing Plant

   19	dollars
                                                   XXX
                  Figure 4-2.  Sample model  plant  data form.
                                            4-13

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                                        Model Plant Form (con.)
                                                  Alternative 1
                                                    (Baseline)
                                                                        Alternative 2
                                                                                            Alternative n
 9, Expected Life of Compliance
    Equipment for Existing Plant (years)

10. Lott Productive Time While Compliance
    Equipment It Installed in Existing Plant (days)

11. Salvage Value, if any, of Compliance
    Equipment When Plant Is Closed
    19	dollars

12. Total Annual Operating Costs
    19	dollars

13. Annual Fixed Operating Costs
    Total Fixed Operating Cost
    19	dollars

    Labor

    Number of labor hours
    Annual Wage per labor hour
    18	dollars
    Labor Cost 19	dollars

    Energy Costs 19	dollars
    Materials Costs 19	dollars
    Overhead Costs  19	dollars
    Other Fixed Costs 19	dollars

14. Annual Variable Operating Costs
    Total Variable Operating Costs
    19	dollars

    Labor

    Number of labor hours
    Annual Wage per labor hour
    19	dollars

    Labor Cost 19	dollars
    Energy Costs 19	dollars
    Materials Costs 19	dollars
    Overhead Costs 19	dollars
    Other Variable Costs 19	dollars

15. Current Salvage Value of Plant
    19	dollars    	
XXX
XXX
XXX
16.  Salvage Value of Plant at End of Life
    19__ dollars

17.  Residuals Discharged to Environment
    To Atmosphere
    Name 	'.	
    Quantity

    To Water

    Name _
    Quantity

    To Land
    Name	
    Quantity
                                      Figure 4-2. (con.)
                                            4-14

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
          Unit process:   A unit  process  corresponds  to  a single treat-
          ment  operation.   Examples  of   unit  processes  are  secondary
          clarification, filtration, and cyanide destruction.

          Treatment process:   A  treatment  process  is  a  sequence of one
          or more unit processes linked together to support a particular
          pollutant-removal process.   For  example,  the  activated sludge
          process  involves the  decomposition of  organic pollutants  by
          microorganisms.  This operation requires a number of unit proc-
          esses  including  aeration,  sedimentation,  and sludge  reactiva-
          tion.

      •  .  Treatment train:  A  treatment train  is a  sequence  of treatment
          processes.  For  example,  an  advanced treatment train may con-
          sist of  the following treatment processes:  preliminary screen-
          ing, primary settling treatment,  secondary biological treatment,
          and nutrient removal  by chemical  addition.

As discussed below, cost estimates  for benefit-cost  assessments of water qual-
ity programs should  be  broken  down  at  least to the  treatment  process  level
and,  in some cases, to the  unit process  level.

Estimating Treatment  Costs

     Cost  estimation  requires  a  specification .of the  treatment  train . to  be
used.   A waste  treatment train  can be described by a flow diagram  showing
the  relation  and  function  of  the various  treatment and  unit  processes.  One
way to proceed  is to (1) specify  the .important design parameters  (such as
flow, influent  and effluent concentrations,  and contact time) of each  unit in
the treatment process,  (2) calculate the resource requirements  (for  example,
for site preparation  and construction  and  for purchased equipment,  energy,
and  labor) of each unit, (3)  estimate  the  indirect  costs, and  (4) sum to ob-
tain a total cost.  This  calculation  is carried  out  separately for a total capital
and  a total O&M cost  before they  are combined into  a present value or annual -
ized cost.

     Before  illustrating  how   different sources   of cost information  can  be
applied  in particular  situations,  it  is useful to distinguish among four differ-
ent approaches that are employed  to  make cost estimates:

          A total system  estimate

          A planning level  estimate

          An engineering estimate

          A contractor estimate.

The cost  estimates produced  by these techniques range from gross to  refined,
depending on the  different stages of a project, which range from  project con-
ceptualization to  request  for  contractor bids.   The four  costing techniques
                                    4-15            U.S. EPA Headquarters Library
                                                           Mail code 3201
                                                    1200 Pennsylvania Avenue NW
                                                       Washington DC 20460

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
provide  a  convenient frame  of reference for discussion  purposes .but do not
imply  that rigid distinctions  can  always be  made in  using  one  technique
versus another in a specific situation.

     The  use  of  site-specific  information   should  result  in  more  accurate
results  than use  of generalized information.   While  it is, of course,  desirable
to develop accurate estimates, the practitioner is always confronted with decid-
ing  how much accuracy  is needed for a  particular  phase of project planning
and  what  level  of effort to commit  to the development of the estimates.   For
the purposes  of water quality standards planning, the planning level estimate
is generally the most appropriate one to  use, and the examples focus on that
level.

          Total  System Estimate.  In contrast to the other three costing
          techniques,  the total  system approach does not attempt to par-
          tition   a  treatment  train  into  treatment  or  unit  processes.
          Usually  only  one  parameter   of  the  treatment  system—for
          example, plant capacity  expressed as daily flow—is used with a
          set  of  cost curves  to  obtain  total  capital and   annual  O&M
          costs.   The  accuracy is ±40 percent.

          Planning Level  Estimate.   This  approach  is   based  on  prior
          analyses of treatment system components  or unit  processes in
          which costs of the  units have  been related to  important design
          parameters.   The  purpose  is  to   allow recombination or  syn-
          thesis of total  costs resulting from any combination of the  unit
          processes using specified  values  ,of  the design  parameters.
          This level of estimate is appropriate for most water quality pro-
          gram  planning  purposes.   Application  of this technique  re-
          quires  that the  practitioner identify  the  major components in
          the  wastewater  treatment train, the associated design param-
          eter  values, and  the access to generalized cost functions for
          the  components.  The  accuracy of this  costing  technique  is
          within  ±30 percent.  The practitioner  may  be  able to  improve
          the  accuracy  of the  estimate if judgments can be made  about
          how site-specific characteristics differ  from average conditions
          embodied in  the generalized cost functions,

          Engineering Estimate.    Like  the planning level  estimate,  the
          engineering  estimate is  calculated  using unit process  data  but
          goes into more  detail on the  unit processes in the  system to
          adjust  specific costs.  This technique  should yield a  cost esti-
          mate within ±15 percent.

          Contractor Estimate.   The  contractor   estimate  is based  on
          specific  engineering  designs—or  design  approaches  coupled
          with   specified  performance  requirements--for the  treatment
          system  and  it's  unit  processes.  The precision  of  the contrac-
          torfs estimate should be within ±5 percent.
                                    4-76

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
4.7  EXAMPLES USING COST TECHNIQUES

     Detailed  engineering cost estimates are unlikely to be available for analy-
ses  of the type  described in this handbook.  Therefore,  this section explores
a  range of techniques, from fairly sophisticated  costing  models  (CAPDET) to
process  handbooks  and  EPA development  documents,  and  presents specific
examples  to show how they are applied.  Their applicability depends on both
the  amount of information and the t'ime and  resources available to the analyst.
States may have  their own  techniques that are equally applicable.  Even  if
specific  information is not  available,  there are  basic  similarities  in the ap-
proaches  to  water treatment problems  taken by different industries.  There-
fore,' the  experience  of other industries  with  similar processes  or pollutants
may provide a reasonable guide for estimating costs.

     A  library of cost information*  is  available  to  the  practitioner,  including
documents and computer programs.  The purpose of  the  following  examples is
to illustrate the  use of various  information sources to estimate costs, particu-
larly planning level estimates.

JExampjeijiii1_:__rfiPijlp__M}|.|  Using EPA peyelojpmejTt^Dqcument

     This example  illustrates the use  of an EPA  Development Document [U.S.
EPA, 1980b] for a specific  industry and the planning level costing approach.
Assume that more stringent effluent standards will be  imposed  on a 900-ton-
per-day kraft  pulp  mill to meet water  quality standards.  Based on a waste-
load allocation, the  effluent concentrations required to meet  the  water  quality
standards  are  15 mg/L for both biochemical oxygen  demand (BOD)  and  total
suspended solids  (TSS).   The  costs  are  to be estimated for  October 1981.t
The practitioner  determines that the  mill  belongs to the "Market Bleached
Kraft"  subcategory (described  as  one  of  the  industry subcategories  in the
Development  Document)  and  that  concentrations  of BOD  and  TSS  in the
plant's  effluent  stream  currently  are  20 mg/L  and  30 mg/L,  respectively,
which meet Best  Practicable Technology (BPT) standards.^  The Development
Document identifies three  treatment options that might  possibly be used to
meet the  new  BOD and  TSS  targets,  but  only  Option 3,  which  consists of
additional in-plant  process controls together with chemically assisted clarifica-
tion  of  the  final  effluent, can achieve  the BOD and TSS targets of the water
quality standards.
     *lmportant sources include:  (1) EPA Development  Documents for effluent
limitations  guidelines and standards  (issued  by the Effluent  Guidelines Divi-
sion of EPA  to provide the technical  background for the development of waste
treatment rules for particular industries);   (2)  Areawide Assessment Proced-
ures  Manual   [U.S.  EPA, 1976];  (3) Innovative and  Alternative Assessment
Manual [U.S.  EPA, 1980a].

     fThe  examples  in this  guidance use historical values of treatment cost
indexes.    For planning  purposes  it may  be  necessary  to  estimate  future
values.
           standards  for the  pulp,  paper and  paperboard industry  have not
yet been promulgated.

                                   4-17

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     The next step is to  estimate the cost for Option 3.  Table 4-3  shows the
costs of  meeting  Option 3 for three  model  mills with sizes of  350, 600,  and
1,600  tons per  day.  Note  that  energy costs  are  presented separately,  so
they  must be combined with  O&M costs  to obtain the definition of O&M costs
used  here.  Two costs are  shown for  each  category of cost based on  alum
concentration.   As  a  first approximation, an  average cost for the two  alum
concentrations  is  used.  Next, because  none of the three model mill  sizes is
                 Table 4-3.   Example 1:   Cost Summary—
                   Market Bleached Kraft, Subcategory
Mill size
(tons/day)
Capital cost 350
600
1,600
Annual O&M cost 350
600
1,600
Annual energy cost 350
600
1,600
Incremental
compliance costs .
from BPT: Option 3 '
6,662
8,974
9,446 ,
16,590
17,410
947
1,327
1,327
1,953
2,974
4,550
212
517
351
358
897
917
SOURCE:  U.S.  EPA [1980b], p. 468,  Table IX-7.

aFirst quarter 1978 thousands of dollars.

 Dollar  value shown above the line is based on chemical assisted clarifica-
 tion dosage of  alum at 150 mg/L;  the value below the line  is for dosage at
 300 mg/L.
                                   4-18

-------
I
I
mm .

I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
for a  900-ton-per-day plant, a linear  interpolation  based on mill  size is made
between the values for the 600- and 1,600-ton-per-day plants.* This yields a
capital cost for Option 3  of $11.5 million.   Annual  O&M cost  is  $2.3 million,
and energy cost  is  $0.5 million;  these  are added for a  total  O&M cost of
$2.8 million.
     The following  steps  show the  results for various measures of  social  cost
derived from  the  basic  costs,  which  are used  as part  of the  benefit-cost
.assessment.  The following parameter values are used:
     ENR index (1st Qtr 1978) =2,683
     ENR index (Oct 1981) = 3,679
     EPA O&M index (1st Qtr 1978) = 2.30
     EPA O&M index (Oct  1981) = 3.34
     s = real social discount rate = 0.10 or O.OSf
     L = average equipment lifetime = 15
     d = depreciation  rate = 1/L = 1/15
     N - planning .period = 30 years

The indexes  are  historical  values,  the other parameters are assumed values.
The results are  (all  quantities in thousands  of  1981  dollars unless  otherwise
noted):
     1.   Capital  treatment costs:
          K  =  11,500  (1st Qtr 1978 $)
          K  =  11,500  xfigf

          K  =  15,800  (Oct 1981 $)
     2.   O&M treatment costs:
          OM = 2,800 (1st Qtr 1978 $)
     *Another method for estimating  the value for the 900-ton-per-day  plant
size is to fit a cost  curve to the three data points to determine if there are
economies of  scale of treatment costs instead of assuming a linear relationship
between mill size and cost for the two larger model mills.
     TThese are  just sample  values  chosen  to  show the effects of different
values  on the results.  See Chapter 2 for discussion of which discount rate to
use.
                                    4-19

-------
1
1
^^B


I
•
1



1

1

1
•
•



1



1

1

1

1

1
1

1


3 34
OM = 2,800 x |^|2
2.30

OM = 4,100 (Oct 1981 $)







3. Present value factor (equals present value of payment of one dollar
per year for N years at discount rate s):
PV(30, 0.10) = 9.43

PV(30, 0.05) = 15.37
4. Present value of O&M costs:
PVOM = OM • PV(30, 0.10) = 4,100 • 9.43
- OM • PV(30, 0.05) = 4,100 • 15.37




= 38,700
= 63,000
5. Reinvestment cost (assume the entire facility is .replaced in 15 years
at the same original real cost):*
RC = K = 15,800


6. The present value of the reinvestment cost is found by discounting
at rate s over 15 years:

PVRC = RC • (1+s)"L = 15,800 • <1.1)"15 =
= 15,800 • (1.05)"15
7. Salvage value (assume zero salvage value)

SV = 0
8, Present value of salvage (salvage occurs
N):
PVSV = SV (1+s)~N
= 0
9. Present value of salvage (salvage occurs
N):
*

*Not all structures would need to be replaced
to represent the average lifetime of the facility.

4-20



= 3.800 (s = 0.10) or
= 7,600 (s = 0.05)
*


at end of planning period,



at end of planning period,


. Fifteen years is assumed





-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
          PVSV = SV (1 + s)"N

                = 0

    10.   Total  present value of investment cost:

          PVK - K + PVRC - PVSV

               = 15,800 + 3,800-0 = 19,600(5 =

               = 15,800 + 7,600 - 0 = 23,400 (s = 0.05)

    11.   Total  present value of project cost:

          TPV = PVK + PVOM

               = 19,600 + 38,700 = 58,300 (s = 0.10)

               = 23,400 + 63,300 = 86,400(s = 0.05)

    12.   Annualized capital  costs:

          KANN = PVK/PV =  19,600/9.43 « 2,080 (s = 0.10)

                          = 23,400/15.37 = 1,520(5 = 0.05)

    13.   Total  annualized costs:

          TAG = KANN + OM =  2,080 + 4,100 = 6,180 (s =  0.10)

                            = 1,520 + 4,100  =  5,620 (s = 0.05)

The  total present value  of  project  costs calculated  in Item 11 above  is the
amount that would be included  in the benefit-cost assessment.  Alternatively,
the total  annualized  cost  (Item  13 above) would be  used if  the  rest  of the
assessment were also expressed in terms of annualized costs.

Example 2:  POTW Using  CAPDET

     Over the past  decade  a number of computer-based  treatment cost esti-
mating  models have  been developed; CAPDET  is  one of the more widely used
models  [U.S.  EPA,  1981].*  CAPDET is  not a  mathematical optimization model;
the CAPDET  approach  is  to prepare cost estimates  for alternative treatment
trains  specified  by  the user.  With reference  to the  four costing techniques
discussed earlier, the CAPDET method is probably best described  as an  inter-
mediate method  between the  planning level approach and the engineering esti-
     *To obtain access  to  CAPDET  programs and  documentation,  contact the
Systems Analysis Group of EPA regional offices or the Facilities and Require-
ments Division, Office of Water Program Operations,  EPA in Washington, D.C.
                                   4-21

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
mate  approach.   CAPDET  contains cost and  performance equations for-35 unit
processes such  as activated sludge,  carbon  absorption,  lagoons, incineration,
etc.   For  some  unit processes,  alternative  design approaches are included;
for example, the activated sludge process is described  by  13 different meth-
ods  of aeration.  Two separate  cost  estimating methods are  incorporated in
CAPDET.  First,  parametric cost estimating  is  based  on statistical analysis of
the  cost of facilities  of  similar size and characteristics  at other locations.
Second,  unit cost  estimating  is based  on  identification of cost elements to
which input prices  are applied—e.g., cubic yards of  concrete  in  a  clarifier
are quantified  and  an input cost value for  reinforced  concrete  is  applied to
obtain a  construction cost.

     After recent revisions, CAPDET can  be  used to estimate costs of  upgrad-
ing an existing  POTW even  though  the  program  was developed originally to
estimate  new plant costs.   Its capabilities  have also been expanded to provide
estimates of financial impacts on  households  from the construction of a POTW
facility.

      In this example, an existing municipal POTW has  an average daily flow of
5 Mgal/d, a maximum flow  of 10 Mgal/d, and effluent  concentrations of 15  and
20 mg/L  for BOD and  TSS,  respectively.   Current secondary treatment uses
plug  flow  for  the  activated sludge  effluent,   and the  practitioner needs to
determine the cost of upgrading the treatment  by chemical  addition and  filtra-
tion  to meet the water quality standard that  requires reductions of  BOD to
10 mg/L  and TSS to  1 mg/L or less.

     To  use the  CAPDET computer program,  the unit  processes in the current
plug  flow system and the upgraded  treatment  are  specified  as  shown in Table
4-4.  The  CAPDET  program  can accept any number  of wastewater treatment
trains that are suitably  described by the user.
             Table 4-4,  Example 2:  Current and Upgraded
                      Treatment Trains for  CAPDET
   Current treatment sequence
Upgraded treatment sequence
      Raw sewage
      Preliminary treatment
      Primary clarifier
      Plug  flow
      Secondary clarifier
      Chlorination
      Gravity thickener
      Anaerobic digestion
      Vacuum filtration
      Hauling and land fill
  Raw sewage
  Preliminary treatment
  Primary clarifier
  Plug flow
  Secondary clarifier
  Coagulation
  Filtration
  Chlorination
  Gravity thickener
  Anaerobic  digestion
  Vacuum filtration
  Hauling and land fill
                                  4-22

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
    Table 4-5.  Example 2:   Price and  Cost Inputs  to CAPDET
                  Cost analysis  input parameters
              Interest  rate:         10.000 percent
              Planning period:       30 years
              Year of dollars used:  1980
          Cost Indexes
Buildings
Excavation
Wall concrete
Slab concrete
Marshall and Swift Index
Crane rental
EPA Construction Cost Index
Canopy roof
Labor rate
Operator class 11
Electricity
Chemical costs
     Lime
     Alum
     Iron salts
     Polymer
Engineering  News Record  Cost Index
Handrail
Pipe Cost Index
Pipe installation labor rate
8-in.  pipe
8-in.  pipe  bend
8-in.  pipe  tee
8-in.  pipe  valve
  Unit  prices
   55.00 $/ft2
    7.00 $/yd3
  207.00 $/yd3
   91.00 $/yd3
  577.00
   67.00 $/h
  163.00
   15.75 $/ft2
   13.40 $/h
    9,00 $/h
    0.04 $/kWh

    0.03 $/lb
    0.04 $/lb
    0.06 $/lb
    1.62 $/lb
2,886.00
   25.20 $/ft
  295.20
   14.70 $/h
    9.08 $/ft
   86.82 $/unit
  128.49 $/unit
1,346.16 $/unit
                               4-23

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     Table 4-5  shows unit  costs  and prices in 1980 dollars that the practi-
tioner  provides  to CAPDET,  as  well  as  the  planning  period  and interest rate
to  be  used  in  computing  project costs.    In  calculating  the  capital  costs,
CAPDET recognizes that each equipment  item has a service life  associated with
it that may  be  less  than the planning  period  and  that  the  facility has  some
salvage value at  the  end of the  planning  period.   As  a result,  the  capita!
cost incorporates  three components,  initial and  reinvestment costs and salvage
value.   Typical  useful  life  periods  are as follows:   wastewater conveyance
structures,  50 years;  other  structures, 30 to 50 years;  process equipment,  15
to 20 years;  and  auxiliary equipment, 10 to  15  years.  In addition, O&M costs
can be specified  to vary over the planning period.

     Table 4-6 summarizes the costs of the two  systems analyzed by CAPDET,
a new  treatment plant using the current treatment  sequence and a  new plant
with the two  new  treatment steps  included.  The table also  shows the unad-
justed  cost  increments obtained from CAPDET  for  upgrading  the POTW and
the adjusted costs which  are increased  by 15  percent to reflect the costs  of
retrofitting an existing system.

     The capital costs of  upgrading (as shown in Table 4-6) are $1.01 million;
total project costs are $1.81 million.  Additional  O&M costs  (which vary be-
tween  the  first and  final year)  range  from $370,000  to  $200,000  annually.
Present worth is.$5.46 million;  annualized  cost  is $580,000  based on  a 30-year
planning period and 10 percent rate of interest.
         Table 4-6.   Example 2:  POTW Upgrading Cost Summary
                        (millions of 1980  dollars)
                                                         Incremental
  New       New POTW with
POTW with     plug flow    costs for upgraded  POTW
plug flow    and chemical  	**	
secondary    addition  and   CAPDET   Adjusted for
treatment    filtration    unadjusted     retrofit
Capital cost
Total construction
3.60
4.40
4,48
5.46
0.88
1.06
1.01
1.22
    cost

  Total project
    cost

  O&M cost
  6.53
8.10
1.57
1.81
First year
Final year
Present worth
0.31
0.46
9.98
0.63
0.63
14.76
0.32
0.17
4.78
0.37
0,20
5.46
 Adjusted costs are 15 percent higher than unadjusted costs.
                                  4-24

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 Example 3:   POTW Using Technology Assessment  Manual
      In this example, planning level estimates of costs for upgrading an exist-
 ing  facility are developed  from generalized  cost curves  that have been devel-
oped
[U.S.
in the 'EPA's Innovative and Alternative Technology  Assessment Manual
 EPA,  1980a].   The manual has  been designed specifically to aid Federal
and State  review  authorities  in the administration of innovative  and alternative
requirements of the Construction Grants Program and to provide basic method-
ological  and technical  information  to  individuals involved in facility plan  de-
velopment.

     A municipality  is  assumed to  have  secondary wastewater  treatment in
place at the POTW using the activated  sludge process.   Wastewater flow is 10
Mgal/d,  and the  effluent  has a monthly  average  value of 30 mg/L for  both
BOD  'and  TSS.   To meet  an ultimate  oxygen  demand  (UOD)* of 85 mg/L as
part of waste-load allocation, it has been determined that the advanced waste
treatment  process described  in  the  Manual as  "nitrification,  separate  stage,
with  clarifier"  is required..  The  construction  and O&M  costs  are  obtained
from  Fact  Sheet 2.1.14  in  the Manual using a 10-Mgal/d flow .rate.  Construc-
tion costs are $1,6 million and O&M costs are $70,000 in 1976 dollars.

     Several other  adjustments  to  the  values  read from the cost  curves  are
necessary.  The  referenced  Fact Sheet is based on an  ENR construction cost
index  of 2,475  (for September  1976).  Adjusting the construction costs for a
first quarter  1980 ENR  index of 2,886 yields a construction cost of $1.9 mil-
lion.   The  O&M costs must also be adjusted  to first quarter 1980.  The  EPA
O&M index  for  the third quarter of  1976  is  2.06 and for the  first quarter of
1980  is 2.83,  yielding  an  adjustment  factor of  1.37.   Therefore,  O&M costs
are $100,000.

     The Fact Sheet in the  Manual directs the  user to estimate  other  capital
expenditures  that have  not been  included  in the  construction  cost curves.
Table 4-7  replicates Table  A-2, which is  provided for  that  purpose  in  the
Manual.   Following  the  directions  incorporated  with  Table A-2, the  practi-
tioner  estimates  nonconstruction  capital expenditures.   As  shown in Table
4-7, total capital cost is  $3.5  million.

     The  costs of the system are summarized in Table 4-8 together with efflu-
ent  information.  The  annualized  costs in the  table  are based  on a  capital
recovery  factor of 0.106,  reflecting a  10  percent social discount  rate and a
30-year plant life.

Example  4:  What To Do When There  Is  "No Information"

     The  practitioner may find that no Development  Document or other techni-
cal  data  have been published that  are directly  applicable to a  particular type
of industrial plant.  Nevertheless,  it  is possible to identify treatment options
and  develop preliminary  cost estimates, suitable for at  least the  early  phases
of water quality program analysis.
     *UOD + BOD5 x 1.5 + NH3 x 4.5.
                                   4-25

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
   Table 4-7.  Example 3:   Development of Capital  Costs (Nitrification)
             (All costs in  millions  of 1st quarter 1980 dollars)

Component installed construction costs
   Unit processes
      Nitrification
   Miscellaneous structures
   (Administrative offices,  laboratories,
     shops and garage facilities)

      Subtotal 1
                                              $1.9

                                              $0.0
                                                        $1.9
Noncomponent costs
   Piping
   Electrical
   Instrumentation
   Site preparation
      Subtotal 2

Nonconstruction costs

   Engineering and construction
     supervision  @ 15 percent.
   Contingencies  @ 15 percent

      Subtotal 3

      Total capital costs
                      Average

                          10%
                           •8%
                           5%
                           5%
                         Range

                         8-15%
                         5-12%
                         3-10%
                         1-10%
                       $0.2
                        0.4
                        0.1
                        0.1
                                              $0.4

                                              $0.4
                                                        $0.8
                                                        $0.8

                                                        $3.5
 Range due to level of complexity, degree of instrumentation,  subsoil con-
  dition, configuration of site, etc., percentage of subtotal 1.
^Percentage of subtotal 1 plus 2.
               Table 4-8.   Example 3:  Summary of Costs
                        for Nitrification  Upgrade
     Costs (millions of 1980:1 dollars)	
 Construe-    Total
   tion       capital      O&M      Annual ized
   costs     . costs       costs  •       cost
    ($)         ($)        ($)          ($)
                                      Effluent  (mg/L)
                                  BOD
                                          UOD*
    1.9
3.5
0.10
0.46
10
19.5
 UOD = BOD5 x 1.5 + NH3 x 4.5.
                                   4-26

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     A reasonable approach is  to first  identify the pollutants that are of major
concern at the  particular plant,  their concentration,  and  the effluent flow.
The next step is to identify  waste  treatment unit  processes that may be appli-
cable  for  the identified pollutants.  This  can be  done by  identifying  one or
more analogous industries--e.g., an  industrial plant where the specific pollut-
ants  of interest  are  being effectively  treated,  or have  been studied.   In all
likelihood, the  method of treatment of  a specific pollutant in one industry will
be applicable  to the particular plant of interest to the practitioner.

     The next step is to  acquire Development Documents and other reports on
the  analogous industries.  Using the information  on the  analogous plants, the
practitioner  should search out the cost-versus-flow-size relationships for the
one  or more  unit processes used to  treat the pollutants of interest.  This will
allow the practitioner to synthesize  a  wastewater treatment train  and estimate
a total cost  for  the process units  in the train.   This  approach  is preferable
to using a total  system  cost estimate, in which the costs  for each  unit process
are not explicitly identified.

4.8  FINAL CAUTIONS

     This  section  describes  several  important factors that suggest caution is
necessary  when  measuring  waste  treatment  costs,  particularly  industrial
wastes.

     The costs  of treating wastes  are  only one element  of the entire produc-
tion  process for a firm.   This  element  is the management of .the residuals that
accompany production (see Ayres and  Kneese  [1969]).   The costs of treating
wastes  can be  affected by changes  in the  level  of production,  which  alters
the  volume of wastes and perhaps the type of treatment required.  Changes
in the type of  product produced,  in the processes used  to  make it, or in the
means  of recovering  the  waste all can affect the cost and  type of treatment
required.  For example, a  technology change in  pulp production for the paper
industry from sulfite  to  kraft  lowered  the volume  of suspended solids.  When
the  practitioner  considers the cost of  a regulatory action,  it is  important to
keep this total system  view in mind,

4.9  SUMMARY

     This section summarizes the major points from the chapter.

          Costs are measured on the basis  of  opportunity cost—the value
          of the next best forgone alternative.

          The two main approaches  to  estimating costs  are the economet-
          ric  and  engineering approach.   The  engineering  approach is
          most often  used because  data needed in the  econometric  ap-
          proach are seldom available.

          Two major cost categories  are capital costs and operation and
          maintenance (O&M)  costs.    Capital  costs are  initial  costs  of
                                    4-27

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
 construction  or upgrading.   Operation and  maintenance costs
 are  annual costs  of  running and maintaining a facility after its
 construction.

 Three  useful   sources  of cost  data are  vendors,  estimating
 manuals,  and  industry information.

 Discounting  links  the four major components of project costs:
 initial investment, Q&M, reinvestment, and salvage value.

 Cost indexes  allow  cost  estimates from  different years to be
 compared  on  a common  basis.   Useful  index  are EPA's Sewage
 Treatment Plant  Construction  Index,  the GNP  price  deflator
 series,  and   Chemical  Engineering   Plant  Construction  Cost
 Index.

 Important factors  affecting costs of  waste  treatment are  flow
 rate,  pollutant loadings,  plant  location,  and  performance  cap-
 ability.

 A model plant data form .can organize information .required for
 costing.

 Three levels of waste treatment are  unit process (single treat-
 ment),  treatment  process (sequence of unit processes),   and
 treatment train (sequence  of treatment processes).

 Planning  level  estimates  of costs  based on  prior  analyses of
 treatment  cost and having an accuracy of  ±30 percent  are  ap-
 propriate for many water quality program decisions.

 EPA  Development  Documents  provide  a  valuable  .source  of
 planning level  costs for specific industries.

 CAPDET  is a  computerized model that prepares  cost estimates
 of  alternative  treatment  trains,  estimates   the  costs  of   up-
 grading,  and  computes a financial impact statement for publicly
 owned treatment  works.  CAPDET provides  accuracy between
 ±15 and ±30 percent.

 Technology assessment  manuals  provide  basic technologies  for
 publicly owned treatment works.

 Treatment cost estimates are sensitive to  many factors in firms'
overall  production  operation, including output  levels, types of
 products, or manufacturing processes.
                           4-28

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                  CHAPTER 5

                COMPLETING THE BENEFIT-COST ASSESSMENT
 5.1   INTRODUCTION

      What is a sensitivity analysis?   How  is it used in a  benefit-cost assess-
 ment?  What  methods are appropriate for displaying the results of a benefit-
 cost  assessment?  Is a checklist of elements possible in a  benefit-cost assess-
 ment?

      In  answering these  questions, this chapter discusses three sets of prac-
 tical  problems encountered  in  benefit-cost assessments:  establishing  plausible
 results,  displaying  those results,  and organizing  the  assessment's  elements.
 The  complexity of these  practical  problems varies directly with the complexity
 of  the  particular assessment.   For  example,  in a  qualitative assessment,  a
 sensitivity  analysis  need  be conducted  only in very general terms.  However,
 in  a  complex  assessment, such as one presented  in the  example below,  the
 plausibility of individual  variables is  specifically considered.   In other words,
 the resources used  in a  sensitivity analysis can be tailored to the importance
 of the decision.

      The following sections of  this chapter highlight these practical aspects of
 a  benefit-cost assessment.   Specifically,  Section  5.2 presents a  sensitivity
 analysis for  a water quality standards example involving  monetized benefits
 and costs.   Section  5,3 describes  narratives,  arrays/ and  graphs as alterna-
 tive ways of displaying the  results of  an  assessment.   Section 5.4 presents a
 checklist for organizing  an  assessment.   Finally,  Section  5.5 summarizes  the
 chapter's main points.

 5.2   SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS:   A GAUGE TO BELIEVABILITY

 Introduction

     One ingredient  in a  good  benefit-cost assessment is a sensitivity analysis
 of its key variables  and  assumptions.  The  most common  variables considered
 in a  sensitivity analysis are  the parameters that  determine benefits and  costs,
the discount  rate, and  the time horizon of the assessment.  For example,  the
effectiveness  of a particular treatment  process may be uncertain so  that  the
anticipated water  quality may not be fully achieved.  As previously discussed,
the discount  rate can  be  among the most  important  of these features because
it affects both  benefits and costs.

     A  sensitivity analysis  establishes  a  range for the  net  benefits in  the
assessment  rather than simply  portraying a single estimate.   In principle, this
is  similar to the  procedure in  statistics that establishes interval  estimates  to
                                      5-1

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
bound the range of possibilities.  In a benefit-cost assessment,  greater uncer-
tainties  in the  estimates of benefits and  costs yield larger bounds to include
most of the possible outcomes.

     A sensitivity analysis will show when  the assessment  is affected by  the
assumptions  made.   In  instances  where  similar  benefit-cost  assessments  are
expected in  the future, a sensitivity analysis can serve as an agenda for  re-
search by highlighting assumptions that  influence the estimated net benefits.
Even when an assessment  is sensitive to the assumptions employed,  its results
are  not  invalidated.   Rather, this sensitivity calls for more care in interpret-
ing the results and in determining whether the assumptions are reasonable.

     A sensitivity analysis employs  high and low estimates  for  both benefits
and  costs and estimates net benefits for  a  range of  discount  rates.  Although
there  are no formal procedures in a  sensitivity analysis,  the following example
highlights the decisions required to implement the  various  steps.
                    Table 5-1.  Key Elements of  Benefit and  Costs

Line item
(and key
assumption)
Cost savings3
Likely estimate
(and range),
$ million
Benefits forgone
Line item Likely estimate
(and key (and range),
assumption) $ million
Capital  costs
  New advanced  waste
  treatment plant
  (size  of  plant)       4,8 (3.0 to  6.0)
  Process changes
  at meat processing
  plant (extent of
  changes)
3.2 (1.2 to 5.0)
Additional  fish-
ing (5 percent
growth rate)

Additional  swim-
ming  (probability
of swimming  is
constant)
                                                                       1.75 (0.50 to 3.0)
0.50 (0.2 to 1.25)
                                          Additional near-
                                          water activities
                                          (no new activities) 0.50  (0.2 to 1.50)
Operating costs
  Advanced treatment

  Meat processing
     1.0

     0.5
 Cost  savings  are the investment and operating costs forgone by not meeting
 the fish  and wildlife propagation use for  river.  Likely estimate  is listed first
 with the  range in parentheses.

 Benefits  forgone stem from  the  recreational  activities had the fish and wildlife
 propagation use  been achieved.  Likely estimate is  listed first with the range
 in  parentheses.
                                      5-2

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
 Example

      Suppose a State is  considering changing the use designation for Segment
 30 of a  river from  fish  and  wildlife propagation  (which is not being attained)
 to agricultural uses.  The need  for a  sensitivity analysis is demonstrated  by
 the data in  Table 5-1, which shows the key elements  in the benefit-cost as-
 sessment--cost savings  and  benefits forgone.   Uncertainty  both in the  ulti-
 mate  size of  a new municipal  waste treatment plant and in the estimation of
 the cost savings for the  process change at  a  meat packing  plant dictates the
 bounds  for  the cost estimates.   In this case, the capital cost savings occur in
 the current  year,   so they are not affected by  the  selection of the discount
 rate.

      The estimates  of the  benefits forgone  by  the change in designated  uses
 show  even  more uncertainty.  The value of the estimated loss in fishing activ-
 ities depends on a  5 percent per year increase in  fishing expected under the
 previous designated  uses.  By  varying the assumed increase in fishing  activi-
 ties under the new  designated  uses,  the forgone benefits range from $500,000
 per year to  $3,000,000 per year.  The  estimation of forgone swimming activ-
 ities is  based on the assumption  that the level  of swimming  would not change.
 If  adjustments are  made  for  the  uncertainty of the assumption,  the estimated
 forgone  swimming  benefits  range from  $200,000 per  year  to $1,250,000  per
 year.   The  range of forgone benefits for near-water  activities depends  on the
 assumption  that  no  new  activities  are  developed  for  the  river.   When  this
 assumption  is relaxed, benefits for near-water activities range from  $200,000
 to $1,500,000.

 Step 1:   Translate the Benefits and Costs into  Present  Values

     The first step in   sensitivity analysis  is to  translate  the benefits  and
 costs  into  present   values  to make the net  benefit calculation.   This example
 simplifies the calculations by assuming  a real rate  of 4 percent and a project
-life  of 50 years.  Only  quantified and  monetized  benefits  are  considered  in
 this example,  and   all  capital  costs  are spent  in  year zero.  The problem;
 then,  is  to translate the  annual ,costs  and  annual benefits  that  occur  each
 year into their present value equivalents,  which requires the use  of present
 value  tables.  The  information  needed for using  present value  (PV) tables is
 P/A,* 4 percent,  50  years.  For the most likely case:

     Operating cost  savings   = P = $1.5  (21.482) = $32.2 million

          Total cost  sayings  = 32.2  million   plus  8.0  million  capital  cost  for-
                               gone, or $40.2 million

             Benefits forgone  = P = $2.75 (21.482)  = $59.1 million
     *P/A  is  a heading  found  in  most present  value tables for translating
annual costs into their present value equivalents.
                                    5-3

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 Net benefits calculated for the most likely estimate benefits and costs are:

                Net benefits = PV benefits forgone  - PV cost savings

               $18.9 million  = $59.1 million - $40.2 million

 The assessment of net present value benefits shows the cost savings from the
 change would  be outweighed by the benefits forgone  if the most  likely esti-
 mates  are  used.   Table 5-2 summarizes  -the results  of  calculations for the
 ranges of benefits and costs in addition  to  the most likely case.
                                                                           *
 Step 2:  Perform  Sensitivity Analysis for  Discount  Rate and Key Assumptions

     The sensitivity analysis shown  in  Table 5-3 describes the  bounds for the
 net benefit estimates,  using alternative discount rates and ranges of benefits
 and costs.   Part A of Table 5-3 shows the most likely estimates of net  bene-
 fits calculated with three different discount rates.   Part B of Table 5-3  shows
 the outcomes that  would result for the worst case expected to occur by esti-
 mating the  cost savings at the lowest end of  their range and the benefits fore-
 gone   at  the  highest  end  for  three   different discount  rates.   Part  C of
 Table  5-3  presents  the estimates that  correspond to the most optimistic case,
 with cost  savings at the highest end  of  their  range  and  benefits forgone at
 the lowest  end of their range.

 Step 3:  Interpret Sensitivity Analysis

     The sensitivity  analysis shows  that  the net present  value is sensitive to
 the discount rate in  that the magnitude of the net  cost savings estimates vary
 over a large  range.   However,  changes  in  the discount  rate  alone over the
 range  employed are  not enough to change the direction of the  net benefit as-
 sessment.   In  both the most likely  and the  worst cases the forgone benefits
 exceed the cost  savings for changing  the use designation. Only in the most
 optimistic case, where the cost savings are at the highest estimate  and  bene-
 fits forgone are  at their  lowest do the cost savings exceed the forgone  bene-
 fits .

     The recommendation  that could be made from  the sensitivity analysis is
 that the change  is  likely to produce forgone benefits  greater than  the  costs,
 with only a small chance  that the  results would be otherwise.   To the extent
 there are effects  that cannot be expressed in dollars, this range can also be
 used to  indirectly  define  what the  dollar  value  of  these effects would need to
 be  to  change the  evaluation.  In  the determination  of the appropriate  use
 classification, the decisionmaker could then weigh this small chance.

 5.3  DISPLAYING THE ASSESSMENT  RESULTS

     This  section  discusses three  methods  for displaying the  results of a
 benefit-cost assessment:  narratives, arrays or matrices,  and .graphical dis-
 plays.   Each method is described briefly, along with  its  advantages and dis-
advantages.
                                    5-4

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
             Table 5-2.   Sensitivity Analysis Calculations:  Discount
                                Rate at 4 percent
          Cost savings, $
     Benefits forgone, $
Capital  cost:  8.0 million in 1982
  Range:   4.2 to 11.0

Operating  cost:  1.5 per year
  Range:   None

Present value of operating costs:
  32.2 million

Present value of total (most likely
  case):  40.2

Range of  present values of total
  cost savings:   36.4 to 43.2  million
Recreation:  2.75 per year
  Range:   0.9 to 5.75  per year
Present value:  59.1 million
  Range:   19.3 to  123.5  million

Total (most likely case):  59.1


Range of total benefits forgone  for
  all cases:  19.3 to 123.5 million
                        Table  5-3.   Sensitivity Analysis
          Discount rate
      Net present value
     of cost saving  minus
       benefits forgone
          (million $)
         A.  Most Likely Levels of Benefits  Forgone and  Cost Savings
               2
               4
               6
            -31.3
            -18.9
            -11.7
      B.   Cost Savings at Lowest  Estimate—Benefits Forgone at  Highest
               2
               4
               6
           -129.4
            -87.1
            -62.8
      C.   Cost Savings at Highest Estimate—Benefits Forgone at Lowest
               2
               4
               6
             29.9
             23.9
             20.5
                                    5-5
                                                     U.S. EPA Headquarters Library
                                                           Mail code 3201
                                                     1200 Pennsylvania Avenue NW
                                                        Washington DC 20460

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 Narratives

      A narrative uses words to describe the results  of an  assessment.   It can
 be used  to  describe  either  qualitative  or quantitative  information  and is a
 simple, straightforward  approach to displaying the results of  an assessment.
 Its main  disadvantage arises when there  are  several types of beneficial  and
 detrimental effects  to  be weighed  in the water quality decision.  The evalua-
 tion  of these diverse benefits and  costs may be aided by expressing some of
 them  with  numerical estimates  of  benefits  and costs.  Combining  narrative
 information with the array  method discussed below can ease the comparison of
 benefits and  costs.  Examples of narratives  used in  combination  with matrices
 are shown throughout Chapter 6.

 Arrays                                                                 '

      An array,  or  matrix,  is a tabular display that contains written and  nu-
 merical descriptions of the outcomes  of  an assessment.  Arrays are most ef-
 fective when  combined  with  the  narrative display  method discussed  above.
 An array organizes  information  in a simple yet visually effective manner.   By
 including  qualitative  information,  the  practitioner  can  easily  describe  the
 nature of the benefits and  costs  and the degrees of confidence in  the esti-
 mates of  either.  If quantitative and  monetized information is included,  it  can
 be supplemented with descriptions of  any  benefits  and  costs  that are  not
 monetized or cannot be quantified.

      Arrays may be readily  adapted to the wide variety of cases likely to be
 encountered  in  an  assessment  of water  quality  programs.   They do  not
 require assumptions about the relationships among  the variables presented in
 the array,  and  they make it easier for the  practitioner  to describe relation-
 ships  known  only in various degrees of  accuracy.   Arrays are particularly
 well-suited  for  displaying intangible benefits and costs  and are  used in both
 Chapter 2 and Chapter 6 to highlight these issues.  Most effective arrays  are
 used  to organize information and  to  display  substantive  descriptions  of  the
 information  presented.   Arrays   that  present  too much  information can  be
 divided into  several arrays,  but care is required  to avoid unnecessary con-
 fusion.   Inadequate descriptions  may be  worse because  they  require that
 users invest their own time.

 Graphs

     Graphs are an effective way of  presenting  information  in a benefit-cost
 assessment,  but  considerable  caution  and scrutiny  are  advised  when  using
 them.   Graphs  can  effectively show relationships between  two variables,  but
 often  the information required to draw  them is simply not available.   These
 problems  are  less important for pie charts and bar graphs but are .prevalent
for tradeoff curves, which  show relationships between two  well-defined objec-
tives.

     Figure 5-1  presents an  example graph that  can  be used for two well-de-
fined  objectives  for a reservoir:   flood control and recreation.   Flood control
is  measured on one  axis in thousand  acre-feet of  water  Impounded  annually,
                                      5-6

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                103 acre
             impounded/yr

                    8
                                  2      3
                                  Recreation
103 visits/yr
                          Figure 5-1.  Tradeoff curve.
and recreation is measured on  the other in visits  per year to the  site..  In
this case, the shape of the curve shows that as more of the reservoir is  used
for a  single objective,  larger  and  larger amounts of the other must  be given
up.

     The tradeoff curve shows a frontier  of alternative combinations of  flood
control and recreation that can be attained with  a  given reservoir in any year.
A  point inside the frontier, like M, represents an inferior, or less attractive,
combination because more  recreation can be  attained while maintaining at  least
the same amount  of  flood control.   However,  the tradeoff curve  provides  no
information  about the relative attractiveness of  points  such as A  through  E.
All are  oh  the frontier,  and  society must choose which  allocation  of the two
objectives is  most  desirable.   The  extreme  points A and  E clearly show that
substantial  amounts  of either  flood control or  recreation must be given  up for
an  exclusive  use.  However, to know whether they are efficient from  society's
viewpoint requires that the value of each good be  known.  The economic prin-
ciples  behind the demand  curve (which  indicates that people will  buy more as
price  is  lowered) imply that  there may  not be a simple one-to-one  relation
between extra units of a commodity and the extra  value from each unit.

     While a useful concept, tradeoff curves are inappropriate  in  many bene-
fit-cost  assessments.  Many assessments for water quality policies  will involve
more than two objectives that would be extremely difficult to express  in a sim-
ple tradeoff relationship.   For  example,  it is unlikely that suitable  quantitative
units   could be derived  to meaningfully express such  objectives as enhanced
ecological diversity,  which may involve complex relationships that can easily
confuse the practitioner about tradeoff relationships.
                                      5-7

-------

Key Elements
* Results of use attainability assessment
• Other background on river segment, water quality
1. Advanced treatment application
2. Previous standards documents
• List of benefits
• List of costs
• Data on benefits
- Primary
1 . Recreation survey— State
2. Recreation survey— U.S. and region
— Secondary
1. Published Federal, State, and local studies
2. Census
• Data on costs
— Primary
1. Engineering studies of treatment costs
2. Economic cost estimates
3. Financial cost estimates
— Secondary
1. Published Federal, State, and local studies
2. Financial/investment sources
• Techniques selected for measuring benefits
1. Direct survey
2. Participation survey
3. Travel cost
4. Hedonic
• Techniques selected for measuring costs
1 . Engineering estimates
2. Computer-assisted model ing techniques
3. Economic cost estimates
• List of key assumptions in measuring
benefits and costs
• Discount rate
• Time horizon
• Sensitivity analysis
• Present value of net benefits -
• Assessment of distribution
• Cost impact assessment
• Final assessment document
( .. _.....
Status of Data for Assessment
Not
Applicable







































Available







































Requested







































Unavailable



































•v




Figure 5-2.  Checklist for a water quality standards benefit-cost assessment.
                                5-8

-------
      In  summary,  tradeoff curves  are  convenient display  techniques  but are
 inappropriate when the objectives  are not well  defined  or  easily expressed in
 quantitative or monetized  units.   The  practitioner should  use this technique
 with a great deal of caution and only when substantial data are available.

 5.4   BENEFIT-COST ASSESSMENT  CHECKLIST

      This  section describes a checklist that can be used in organizing  a bene-
 fit-cost  assessment.   The. example  is  for  a water quality standards, case, but
 the checklist is a general one.

      The  checklist in  Figure 5-2  provides a  means, of tracking  the  various
 steps  involved  in  the assessment  process.  This checklist can  be tailored to
 fit the needs of each  assessment by  varying the types of benefits and  costs
 included and by using the columns at  the right-hand side of the list. These
 columns  allow  the checklist  to  accommodate the  range from simple qualitative
 to  complex  quantitative assessments  by  designating the  status  of the  data
 required for the assessment. A qualitative assessment can be conducted  even
 with  such  status  categories  as  "not applicable" and "unavailable."  The  com-
 plex   assessment   is  made   easier  when  the categories   are  "available"  or
 "requested." The larger the "unavailable" category, the more strongly a  State
 should consider using additional  resources,   either inside or  outside  State
 government, to obtain the needed information,  especially  if benefits or  costs
 are  likely  to  be  sizable and  if the  decision  is  unclear  after  a qualitative
.assessment.  For a complex case involving  potentially large  benefits and costs,
 the extra  value of acquiring the necessary data can be substantial.   Data on
 a  specific  water body  and the  use  of the techniques described in this hand-
 book  can  greatly  simplify the  complex quantitative assessment and assist in
 evaluating  a proposed water quality action.

 5.5  SUMMARY

   •  •    A  sensitivity  analysis  for  key  variables   and  assumptions
          employed  in  an assessment  is  essential  for a  plausible assess-
          ment.

          Sensitivity  establishes a  range of outcomes  possible  for  the
          assessment  and will show when the assessment  is  sensitive to
          its assumptions.

          Three key  components of an assessment  that will be essential
          in the sensitivity  analysis are the discount rate and estimates
          of benefits and costs.

          A  narrative  describes the results of an  assessment  in  words.
          Its main advantage is  its simple straightforward  nature, while
          its disadvantage   is  in  presenting  results for  more .complex
          assessments.

          Arrays  or matrices are  tabular displays  that contain written
          and  numerical  descriptions.   Narratives  are  often  combined
                                  5-9

-------
with  the  arrays  as  an  effective display  technique  and are
suited for a wide range of assessments.

Graphs  can  effectively  illustrate relationships  between  objec-
tives  that  are quantified  or  monetized.   However,  the  informa-
tion necessary  for  these display techniques is  frequently un-
available.

Tradeoff curves show  a  frontier of alternative  combinations  of
quantities  for two  objectives.  Caution  and scrutiny  are ad-
vised  in using  these curves  in  an' assessment  because the
necessary  information is  often unavailable or it  is impossible  to
apply to water bodies with a wide range of uses.

A  checklist is one way of organizing the procedures  and infor-
mation in a benefit-cost assessment.
                          5-10

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                  CHAPTER 6

                      BENEFIT-COST--SAMPLE  SCENARIOS
6.1  INTRODUCTION

     In water  quality programs, the benefit-cost assessment  practitioner must
evaluate  a  wide  range  of  policy  actions.   These  could include both minor
changes in designated  uses for an intermittent stream  and major changes .in
designated  uses  or in  advanced  treatment or combined  sewer overflow  to
provide recreation and  intangible benefits that require substantial investments
by cities  and  firms.  Thus, the framework  for evaluating these policy actions
must be capable of  comparing Incremental benefits  and costs for a diversity of
cases yet provide for  a consistency in the application and  presentation of  the
assessment.   Even  though  scenarios  are presented  only for  potential water
quality  standards decisions, the range of issues is broad enough to be useful
to other water  quality programs.

     To  illustrate the  type  of  assessments  that might arise in water quality
programs, this chapter develops three sample scenarios—simple, medium, and
complex.   Each scenario is  designed  to  build on  the preceding one,  as new
dimensions are added.   Each scenario is  introduced by  a brief description of
hypothetical  sample cases.   Each scenario  refers  the reader to the relevant
handbook chapter(s) that provide more detailed discussion on specific issues.

     Although  the step-by-step  framework illustrated in the following scena-
rios is both systematic and  flexible enough to  accommodate most of the benefit-
cost assessment needs of various water quality programs, the values it assigns
to benefits and costs should be  regarded as approximations rather than abso-
lutes.   This  note of caution has nothing to do with the framework itself, but
with the  specific  information--e.g.,  poor   quality data  on linkages between
water quality,  fish  propagation,  and recreational  fishing—used to estimate
either costs or benefits.

     The  following  sections  of  this chapter  present the three scenarios  for
benefit-cost  assessment.   Specifically,  Section  6.2 describes  a simple case
scenario that  uses only qualitative  information, Section 6.3  presents  the medi-
um case scenario,  providing  some quantitative  benefits  and costs,  and Sec-
tion 6.4 contains a complex  case  scenario  involving  multiple  benefits and costs.
Finally, Section 6.5.summarizes the  key issues in the scenarios.
                                     6-1

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
6.2  SIMPLE CASE SCENARIO

Introduction

     The strength of benefit-cost assessment lies in its ability to organize ma-
terial in a consistent manner yet remain flexible enough to accommodate a wide
range  of cases.   This simple scenario  illustrates a qualitative benefit-cost as-
sessment and demonstrates  both the consistency  and flexibility in this evalua-
tion procedure.

     In  many  water quality applications, the  potential  benefits  and costs do
not justify anything more than a qualitative benefit-cost assessment.  Although
a qualitative assessment does  not quantify the information it organizes,  it does
provide  a framework for presenting the character of the individual  problem
and for  describing  the  judgment employed to  make the assessment.   For
example,  water quality standards  decisions  where qualitative assessment  may
be appropriate include stream-specific standards,  such as the following:

          Public water  supply  designations for streams that have never
          been  so used or that—because of  low cost alternatives—are not
          likely to  be so  used in the future.  Possible  changes  include
          removing  the water supply use and  adding  recreation  or  agri-
          cultural uses that the  water supply use might have precluded.

          Primary contact recreation uses for a stream that currently has
          few  access points,  as well  as  water quality limitations.  Pos-
          sible  changes  include  limiting  types of recreation or  changing
          uses to  accommodate agricultural and industrial activities.

Simple Case Scenario Format

I.   Define the Action

     .A* State  is  reviewing  the designated  uses  for a specific  segment  of  a
river currently designated  for  use  as  a public water supply, although it has
never  been used  in  this capacity,  and  for  primary body  contact  recreation.
The action  to be  assessed is the  removal  of the water supply use and the
addition  of an  irrigation use.   The segment  is  located  in a  portion  of the
State that produces a substantial amount of agricultural  products.  The seg-
ment is  a primary source of water  recreation in the area and supports fish-
ing, swimming, and  limited boating.

II.  Translate the Effects  into Beneficial Outcomes and Costs

     Although  the  use change will  cause  slightly lower levels of dissolved
oxygen  and small  increases  in the levels  of  several other  biological  and  chemi-
cal  water  quality  parameters,  recreation activities will  be unaffected.   The
primary  benefit will  be the increase in high-quality water available for  irriga-
                                    6-2

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
tion, resulting in  cost savings  for farmers who presently have irrigated farm-
land or who will be able to irrigate additional farmland.*

      In terms  of forgone  benefits,  the cost of the action is the loss of a poten-
tial  water supply  source.  However, groundwater sources exist, and residents
are  presently  using  them at lower  costs  and are expected to continue  their
use  in  the future.  Nothing (e.g., shortages or contamination) is expected to
threaten these groundwater supplies.                                  .

III.   Calculate  the  Value of the  Beneficial Effects Based on Willingness to  Pay

      The value of  the benefits  of the change would equal the farmers' willing-
ness  to  pay to obtain the water for irrigation  rather  than do without it.   The
benefits are expected to  be  positive  on this  basis, but not necessarily  large
because some alternative irrigation supplies exist.

IV.  .Calculate  the  Value of the  Detrimental Effects  Based on  Opportunity  Costs

      The opportunity cost  of  this action is  loss  of the  potential  source  of
drinking  water.  The alternative supplies  of drinking water make this oppor-
tunity cost near zero.  If future demand and supply of drinking water should
change substantially, the State  could  reconsider the  designated uses because
the long-term physical effects on the water will be limited in nature.

V.    Compare the Total Benefits and Costs

     The benefits  of  the  action  are the amounts the  farmers would be willing
to pay  from this  new irrigation source to irrigate their farmland without the
action.   The  costs of the  action,  however,  are zero,  because they  consist
entirely  of the lost opportunity for an alternative supply of drinking water,
which can be  obtained from  existing  groundwater resources.  Thus, the total
benefits  of the action are greater than the costs.  Therefore,  the  action will
provide  positive net  benefits for the  State and  country.  Recreation activity
will  be  maintained, and cost savings  for farmers will  be greater than the loss
of a potential source of drinking water.

VI.  Assess the Plausibility of the Results

     The  results  are not likely to change under  almost all  possible circum-
stances.   Only if  dramatic  changes occur in  the  drinking  water  situation--
i.e.,  if  groundwater supplies  become  contaminated  or  suddenly  in  short
supply-would  the  outcome be different.
     *This particular  segment  has ample flow but farmers have not been per-
mitted to use  if  for  irrigation.   Withdrawal for irrigation will  not noticeably
affect recreation activities or fish populations.
                                      6-3

-------
6.3  MEDIUM CASE SCENARIO

Introduction

     As  a group, medium cases can  be distinguished from simple and  complex
cases.   While  simple  cases usually  require  only  a qualitative  assessment of
.benefits  and costs,  medium cases normally involve some quantitative measures
of benefits and costs.  Further, while medium cases usually involve only one
type  of  benefit—such as recreation—and the  application  of measurement ap-
proaches and results  from other studies, complex cases often require develop-
ment of case-specific measurement approaches.

     One practical way  to  distinguish between  simple  and  medium cases  is to
conduct  the qualitative  assessment  and  then  to  judge whether  it  provides
enough  information  for  a clearcut decision.   If ;the outcome is not clear, the
more  quantitative medium  case  assessment  may  be  needed.   Water  quality
standards  decisions  that might require medium  assessments include the follow-
ing:

          Fish  and  wildlife propagation  use  for  a stream that  is  not
          being attained because  of  industrial dischargers,   the treat-
          ment options are  limited to high-cost land-treatment  solutions,
          and  the river is  not an important recreation  source.  Change
          could be to provide  for a  less  restrictive fish arid wildlife use
          or for agricultural/industrial use.

          Fish  and  wildlife  propagation use  for  a major river tributary
          with  industrial  dischargers.   A change  in  designated use  to
          accommodate existing industrial  cooling  would  maintain  rela-
          tively low levels of  dissolved oxygen in a large  segment of the
          river,  primarily affecting fishing.  The  assessment would  com-
          pare  the loss  in potential  fishing  benefits with cost savings to
          industrial  firms.

          Fish  and  wildlife  propagation use  for  a stream  whose hydro-
          logical  equilibrium has been  affected by irrigation.   A change
          in  designated  use to accommodate agricultural irrigation would
          cause the  loss of  a potential warm water fishery in the stream.
          The  assessment would compare loss in potential fishing benefits
          with  cost savings to agricultural irrigation users.

          Attaining  a  limited warmwater fishery (sunfish,  carp, catfish)
          use for a  channelized stream would require an advanced treat-
          ment  plant  for municipal   wastes.   One change would  be  to
          provide roughfish passage.  The assessment  would compare the
          loss  in  potential  fishing  benefits  with  the cost of advanced
          treatment.
                                     6-4

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
 Medium Case  Scenario Format                                .     .

 I.    Define the Action

      A State  is  reviewing  the designated  uses  for a  specific  segment  of  a
 river  currently  designated  for agricultural arid  industrial  use and  secondary
 recreation, primarily  boating.  The action  to  be evaluated is  a  use  change to
 provide  a warmwater  fishery  in addition to other uses.   The river segment is
 capable  of sustaining a  warmwater fishery  if  discharges  .from  a  municipal
 treatment plant are reduced  to improve the level of dissolved oxygen.

 II.   Translate the Effects into Beneficial Outcomes  and Costs

      The effects  of  the change will  be an improvement in dissolved oxygen
 levels to  sustain the  warmwater  fishery  under  all flow  conditions.   This
 change will  provide  a  new  source for smallmouth  bass recreational fishing
 while maintaining the existing uses.  The  primary  cost  of  the change will be
 additional  treatment of municipal wastes, but advanced treatment is not antici-
 pated.

 Ml.   Calculate the Value of  the Beneficial Effects  Based on Willingness to  Pay

      A travel cost model  can be used to estimate  the recreational fishing bene-
 fits.  These benefits  are estimated to be $70,000 per year and are assumed to
 remain at  that level  for  the next 20 years.*  This amount represents fisher-
 men's willingness  to pay for the water quality  improvement, but does not meas-
 ure  nonuser  values  or  intangible  benefits  associated with  the  water quality
 improvement.

 IV.   Calculate the Value of  the Detrimental  Effects  Based on Opportunity Cost

     The municipal  discharger will  be  required  to  upgrade  the  quality of its
treatment  plant.   From  engineering  estimates, this upgrading  is  expected  to
 require an initial investment  of $500,000  but no  increases in  operating ex-
 penses.  There Will be a small economic impact on households who  pay for the
treatment services.  (See Chapter 4 for details  on  measuring costs.)

 V.  Compare the  Total Benefits and  Costs

     To  compare  them,  benefits  and. costs must  be converted into  present
values.  Costs  incurred in the present  year are already in present value
terms  ($500,000), but the  benefits  must be  converted  into a  present value
equivalent from a stream of annual  dollars  over 20  years.  Using a social  rate
of time preference  as presented in Chapter 2,  these benefits are discounted
     *See the complex scenario  for  the  use of a travel  cost model to estimate
recreational fishing benefits.  The results are summarized for the medium  case
to minimize duplication among the scenarios.  See Chapter  3  for  general  dis-
cussion of the travel cost approach.
                                      6-5

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
at  2 percent for  a  total 20-year  value of $1,148,000,   Thus,  total benefits
resulting from the change are $1,148,000,  and total costs are $500,000, result-
ing  in  a positive  net  benefit of $648,000.  Adding the new use will therefore
provide benefits in excess of the required  investment costs.

VI.  Assess the Plausibility of the Results

     The key  element  influencing the  sensitivity  of this scenario is the selec-
tion of  the discount  rate.   To determine the plausibility of the results,  net
benefits  should be  calculated  with different discount  rates  and  compared.
Chapter 2 recommended a high  estimate of 5 percent  for  the social rate of time
preference,  and the Office of Management and Budget  (OMB) requires the  use
of 10 percent  for  major  regulations.  Net .benefits calculated with these rates
are listed below.                                  .
               Discount rate
                 (percent)

                    2
                    5
                   10
Net benefits
     ($)
   648,000
   372,340
    95,980
As indicated,  the use change would .produce positive  net benefits  under any
of the three  discount rates,  implying  that  benefit estimates are not sensitive
to the discount  rate  selected.  Sensitivity analyses also may be performed for
the estimates of benefits  and costs--for example,  with  benefits and  costs esti-
mated  at ±30 percent of the average value.   More details on using  sensitivity
analysis  are provided in Chapter 5.

     In  assessing the plausibility of the results one  might .also consider the
distribution effects discussed in  Chapter 2.   In  this sample case these effects
are an inconsequential  part of  the  assessment because no one  group is adv-
ersely affected.   However,  distribution effects  vary  from case to case and
should be addressed.*

6.4  COMPLEX CASE SCENARIO

Introduction

     The complex case scenario is  distinguished from the simple and  medium
case scenarios by several characteristics,  including its consideration of multi-
ple types  of  tangible benefits,  intangible  benefits, and investment in  waste
treatment  beyond the technology-based requirements.   In addition,  benefits
and costs  in  complex cases are  likely  to be an  order  of magnitude, or more,
above  those in medium  cases.   In fact,  if benefits and  costs are not signifj-
     *The  complex scenario that follows provides a detailed  assessment of dis-
tribution effects.
                                      6-6

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 cantly greater than those of the typical medium case  scenario, use of the com-
 plex  case scenario is not  recommended  because  the effort it  requires  would
 not be justified.                            .

     Measurement  and  valuation  of  benefits  and  costs  may require several
 methods discussed in  Chapters 3 and 4.  The  types .of benefits  and costs, data
 availability,  and  available  staff resources will influence the  level of detail in
 the  assessment.   For controversial  decisions,  a  State  may  decide to obtain
 assistance from outside the agency to  conduct the assessment.

     Complex cases may include the following:

          Adding  fish  and  wildlife   propagation  and  primary contact
          recreation   use  designations for  a  stream  that will  require
          advanced treatment for municipal  discharges.   Benefits  will
          include  multiple   types of  recreation  activities,   intangible
          benefits such  as  enhanced  ecological diversity,  and  nonuser
          benefits.    Costs  will  include  .investments   by  firms  in  waste
          treatment  beyond  investment  required  for technology-based
          requirements.

          Providing public  water  supply  from  a stream  that  will require
          advanced treatment for municipal  wastes.  Water supply  bene-
          fits could be for more than one downstream municipality.

 Complex Case Scenario Format

 I.  Define the Action

     A  State  is  reviewing  the  designated   uses  for a  10-mile segment of
 River 1,  located between  Cities A  and B.  The river is  currently  designated
for secondary contact recreation,  but the State  is  considering adding swimming
and fish  and wildlife  propagation.  These uses cannot be attained by imposing
the technologies  required  under the  Clean  Water Act (Section 30i(b)(2)),  but
they could be attained with  more stringent controls on municipal and industrial
point dischargers.

     River 1 drains an  area of  7,386 square miles, and most of  its length is
characterized by steep banks and rugged terrain.  The major point sources of
discharges on  the river segment of interest are iron  and steel  facilities and a
municipal  sewage discharge just outside  City B  and  upstream from City A.

     The  river is navigable  the  entire year, and a considerable amount of coal
is  barged through several  locks and dams  operated  by  the U.S. Army Corps
of Engineers.  River  1 is  currently used for boating  recreation and for activ-
ities near water  at several  parks located along its banks.  The most notable
water  quality  problems limiting  swimming  and fish  and  wildlife propagation
have been associated  with  the dissolved oxygen and  ammonia  levels, with fre-
quent violations of current standards at low flow.
                                      6-7

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
I
 II.
Translate the Effects into Incremental  Beneficial Outcomes, Costs, and
.Economic  Impacts

A.   Benefits

          Recreational fishing
          Swimming
          Activities "near water"
          Navigation
          Ecological diversity
          Nonuser/nonuse benefits.
     B.   Costs
               Capital, and operating costs for steel plants
               Capital and operating cost for City B

     C.   Distributional Impacts

               Reduced profitability of steel plants
               Effects on operations (will shutdowns occur?)
               Increased sewer charges for municipal taxpayers
               Employment
               Price
               Impact on firms within industry

III. Calculate the Value of Beneficial  Outcomes Based on Willingness to Pay

     •A.   Recreational Boating Benefits

          Step 1

          Determine what data are  available for recreation  on or near River 1.
Likely sources  include the  State  recreation  plan,  the EPA 208  management
plan,  the  1977  Department  of  Interior outdoor recreation  survey, and  the
U.S. Army Corps of Engineers.

          Step 2

          Use  the  Corps of  Engineers  recreation  survey  data on  River 1,
which  contains information  on users  and where  they are from.   This informa-
tion  will allow estimation  of recreation  benefits  with the simplest version of
the  travel  cost  model.   (See  Chapter 3  for  more  details on  travel  cost
models.)

     A  number of  implicit  assumptions  are  used in this scenario.  For  ex-
ample, the State  is assumed to  have the information necessary  to estimate the
current  and  potential  demand  for fishing  and  swimming for  River 1.  The
simplest  measure  of travel  cost is used even though it excludes  the cost of
travel  time,  time spent onsite,  and the influence of substitute sites  on  the
demand for River 1 recreation.   Also assume  that the  travel cost to the site
                                    6-8

-------
is capable  of  capturing all the  factors that influence the decision  to  fish or
swim along the  river.   This  implies  that no  changes  in access, docks, and
other  site  features  are occurring.  (See the case  study of the travel  cost
model in Chapter 3.)

     Equation  (6.1)  illustrates the  travel cost demand equation for these as-
sumptions.   The equation  omits  several origin-specific variables (such  as in-
come,  age,  education,  etc.) that determine recreational demands for  a site be-
cause  they  would  only change  the  position  of  the demand curve for each
origin  zone. The subscript i  refers  to these omitted variables:
                                            A)
(6.1)
where

        A =  activities  that would  be permitted  by the water quality use classi-
             fications (A = B for beatable, F for fishable, S for swimmable),

       V. =  number of visits to the site from origin zone i,  and

     POP. =  population of origin zone i.

          Step 3

          Calculate  recreation benefits for existing water quality  level.   These
calculations are needed to obtain the baseline and must be  netted out from the
benefits of the additional use designations.  Use  the data in Table 6-1 to esti-
mate travel cost model.   Remember:  these are user benefits  only.
         Table 6-1.  Demand for Recreation for River 1—Water Quality
                          at Level Suitable for  Boating
Limits
of zone
of origin
(miles)
1 to 20
21 to 40
41 to 60
61 to 80
81 to 100
100+

'1980
population
(1,000)
1,000
1,500
2,000
2,500
3,500
5,000

Total No.
party visits
1,650,000
600,000
200,000
50,000
25,000
2,500

Visits per
1 ,000
population
1,650
400
100
20
7
0.5
Consumer
surplus per
individual
($)
2.40
1.80
1.40
1.00
0.60
0.20
                                      6-9

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     Calculation  of  Benefits
                            n
              Benefits  =
     TO*

,   .'/VP.'
   TC -
B)dp.
(6.2)
          Benefits = (number of individuals) x (benefits  per individual)
where
     TC* = the travel cost at which there would be a zero visit rate, and

     TC.  = travel cost for ith origin zone.

     Figure.6-1  illustrates  the  consumer  surplus estimates that  result  from
this calculation.   Two assumptions  are  implicit  for the  estimation.  First,  as
with XYZ in Figure 6-1, calculate the representative individual's consumer sur-
plus in an origin zone,  and then assume that all individuals in the origin  zone
have the  same  consumer  surplus.  This  procedure  is  possible  because use
(i.e.,  the  visit  measure)  is  considered  to arise from  the population  as  a
whole.   (The  calculation  would  be  different for travel  cost  models estimated
from survey data.  See Chapter 3 for specifics.)
                 Travel
                 Cost
                 $/visit
                                   Consumer
                                    surplus
                                            fi(Pi,B>
                                                     Pop

                     Figure 6-1. Travel cost demand function and
                       consumer surplus with boatable water.
     For  example, in  Table 6-1,  the fifth column  reports an example of the
estimated individual  consumer  surplus by  origin zone.  Multiplying each  con-
sumer  surplus times the population and adding across  origin zones  gives the
aggregate consumer surplus for the site  with boatable water:
                                      6-10

-------
1
1
1
^^p
1

1
•



1




1







1

1
•

1
•P_
1








1
••
1
M
\


6
Benefits for Boatable Water, 1980-81 = \ population x (consumer surplus
^•4 per individual)

Zone 1
A-
= '$(1,0.00,000 x 2.

Zone 4
+ ' 2,500,000 x 1

= $(2,400,000 + 2,
+ 2,100,000 + 1,
Benefits for Boatable Water =


B. Recreational Fishing
Step 1

Use the results on
(see travel cost case study,
zone i=1
Zone 2 Zone 3
A *.
40' +f 1,500, 000 x 1.80" +'2, 000, 000 x 1.40'

Zone 5 Zone 6
.00"+ 3,500,000 x 0.60' +'5,000,000 x 0.20)*

700,000 + 2,800,000 + 2,500,000
000,000)
$13.5 million for the site with current water
quality levels.

Benefits

fishing benefits in the Monongahela River study
Chapter 3, for details). The results from the
Moripngahela study can be used to calculate benefits analogous to those re-
ported in Table 6-2. Note:
determining the plausibility
River 1 and the Monongahela
practitioners might consider three questions in
of results: What similarities exist between
River? What are the problems in adapting the
results? How significant are they?
Table 6-2. Demand for Recreation for River 1 --Water Quality
at Level Where
Limits
of zone 1980
of origin population
(miles) (1,000)
1 to 20 1,000
21 to 40 1,500
41 to 60 2,000
61 to 80 2,500

81 to 100 3,500
100+ 5,000

a
Gamefish (Bass) Can Live in River
Consumer
Visits per surplus per
Total No. 1,000 individual
party visits population ($)
3,400,000 3,400 0.10
1,500,000 1,000 0.10
800,000 400 0.10
500,000 200 0.10

350,000 100 0.10
50,000 10 0.10


These calculations assume a parallel shift in demand. It need not be parallel
in particular applications (see



travel cost case study, Chapter* 3).

6-11


-------
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
  I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
I
           Step 2               .

           For this framework,  the travel cost model  provides the  relationship
 between the demand for the recreation site and  the water quality use designa-
 tion.    Thus,  an  improvement  in  water  quality from  boatable (B)  to  fish-
 able (F) can be  expected to  shift the demand  for the  site's services.  This
 conclusion  follows  from  the. site's ability to support both types of  recreational
 activities under  the higher designated use.  Figure 6-2 illustrates  the type of
 shift involved.
                                   ^Change in consumer
                                     surplus with
                                       fishable water
                   Figure 6-2. Travel cost demand function and change
                        in consumer surplus with fishable water.
     To calculate the  incremental  benefits associated with this change in use
designation, we need  to estimate YXWV.   In terms of the travel cost demand
model, YXWV would be given as:
              Benefits (incremental to fishable) =
 n            -

E    P°Pi7
                 TC**
 TC*.
F)dp.  -
                TC .
        5=1
   /"
j  J

  TC.
                                                              B)dp.
(6.3)
     The second  term in  Equation (6.3) simply  repeats the benefit estimate
for the  site with  the existing designation which allows boating.  Thus,  the
increment to benefits because  of  the change  in  water quality is  being calcu-
lated.   This example  assumes that individuals from the  same origin zones are
using the site, and  no users  from new  origin zones so  Equation  (6.3) can be
rewritten as the  sum of the increments  to the individual  benefits  realized in
each origin zone, as in Equation (6.4):
                                      6-12

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Benefits for
increment
   to
fishabfe
 water
    n
= E popi
'TC**
/'
                TC*i
f. (p., F)dp. -  J    f.(Pi,  B)dP]
                                   TC
(6.4)
            number of
            individuals
                     increment to each individual's
                     benefits from use designation
For the representative individual, this increment is YXWV in Figure 6-2.

     Table 6-2 reports  some illustrative  increments  in  the fifth column,  and
the calculation process is then similar to that described above,;
Benefits for  Increment
to Fishable Water,  1980-1981
                           Zone 1
                          visits x travel costs
                                 Zone 2
                                       Zong 3
                  = $(1,000,000 x 0.10 +1,500,000 x 0.10  + 2,000,000 x 0.10

                           Zone  4             Zone 5           Zone 6
                            __ _ _  .^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^fc.  .^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^^•••••k
                      '2,500,000 x 0.10 V 3,500,000 x 0.10V5,000,000 x 0.10 x


                  = $(100,000 + 150,000 + 200,000 + 250,000  +

                       350,000 + 500,000)

Benefits for increment .to fishable water = $1.6 million per year.

     C.   Swimming Benefits

          Step 1

          Use  the  results on  swimming  benefits  in the  Monongahela  River
study  (see travel  cost case study,  Chapter 3,  for details) to  calculate  infor-
mation such as that in Table 6-2.

          Step 2

          To calculate  the  benefits from swimming  use, the  frame of reference
must   be defined.   Specifically,  which  incremental  benefits  are  of  more
interest — those associated with moving  from  a fishable to  a swimmable use des-
ignation,  or  those  associated  with moving  from boatable to swimmable?  The
method used  to estimate these  incremental benefits will depend on the refer-
ence point.   For example,  in Figure 6-3, which shows all three demand func-
tions,  movement  from fishable to swimmable  leads to incremental benefits (per
individual) of VWUT.  A change  from  boatable  to  swimmable includes this in-
crement  along with the  increment  associated with the improvement to fishable
(YXWV).


                                     6-13

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                                ^Change in consumer
                                  surplus with
                                    swimmable water
                                                       V
                                                      Pop
                   Figure 6-3.  Travel cost demand function and change
                       in consumer surplus with swimmable water.
     The calculations would follow  the same outline used in the preceding two
examples.   Important in this case  is the  point of  reference  used to calculate
the incremental benefits.  If procedures from previous section are followed:

     Benefits for the increment from fishable to  swimmable water = $750,000.


     D.  , Recreational Benefits of Activities  Near Water

          Improvements  in  water quality will make additional  acres  usable for
activities .near  River 1, including,  for  example, hunting,  birdwatching,  hik-
ing, photography,  and  sightseeing.  This example shows what can be done to
estimate the benefits when  demand  information is not available.  In particular,
a participation  model can be used  to  predict the increase in  recreation activ-
ities near  water and a  recreation day  value estimate  can be  used from other
sources.  (See participation survey  case  study, Chapter 3, for details.)

     An important  issue that arises with  this approach is the consistency  of
benefits derived from the  travel cost  model with  those  from  the participation
model.   Specifically,  the travel  cost model  describes  the demand for  recrea-
tional  site services which  can be used  in a variety of  recreational  activities,
including those "near  water."   Since  the  participation  model for  predicting
demand  for recreation near water may be measuring benefits reflected  in the
travel  cost model, some double counting can occur.

     The following  five  steps can  be  used to  estimate  the  value of the  in-
crease in near-water activities.

          Step  1

          Determine  the availability  of data  on  activities  near  water   for
River  1.
                                    6-14

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
          Step  2

          Estimate the increase in near-water activities resulting  from the fish
and  wildlife propagation use  designation.  Analysis of River 1 determined that
8,931 acres  along  the  river  are  currently  suitable  for  these  activities.
Achieving the  use designation was predicted to make  another 2,700 acres suit-
able for  near-water  activities  and to  improve the recreational  facility  rating
by 1 unit (on a scale of 1 to 5).

          Step  3

          Estimate the  change in the probability  of  participation (AP)  in the
near-water  activities  among the  population  as a  result of the  improvements.
Using  a  model  (see  Chapter 3,  participation  survey case study for details)
that correlates  participation in  near-water activities with available water  recre-
ation area and  a rating of the recreational facilities,  the increased probability
of participation can be calculated as:

AP = 0.38485 /change in acreage of recreationY+ 0.03142/change  in recrea-  ^
             I water available  per capita      j           \ tional  facility  rating
                                                         \
AP = 0.38485
AP = 0.0319.
     2,700   new acres
12,000,000 population  in
           Cities A and B)
+ 0.03142 /I unit improvement
          I  recreational  facility
          \rating
          Step 4

          Estimate  the change  in  participation days attributable  to River 1
between Cities A  and  B.  Specifically, using the national average of 2.0 near-
water  activity days per  participant  per year,  additional  near-water activity
days can be calculated as:                                            •
     Change in near-
     water activity days
                    /change in   \  / Regional\
                   I probability   \ [population \
                   I of. near-water
                    yparticipation

                       (0.03I9)
        I Cities A   I
        \and B    /

      x  (2,000,000)
'Near-water'
 days per
 participant
                                                                      (2.0)
Change in near-water activity days = 127,600/year.

          Step 5

          Estimate  the  value of  additional  near-water  activity  days.   Re-
searchers  have estimated  values per  near-water  activity day .to range from
$12.00 to $18.50 (Volume II  will  provide more details on these values).   Multi-
plying these values  by  the  number  of  additional  near-water activity  days
gives the following range of values for the additional activities:
                                     6-15

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
          (12.00/near-water activity  day)(127,600 days) = $1.5 million

          (18.50/near-water activity  day)(127,600 days) = $2.4 million

 Note:  Remember the limitations of this approach:

       1.  The valuation step  is not based on willingness to pay.

       2.  Limitations  are  caused by transferring the model from one study to
           another.

     E-   Benefits of Improved Ecological  Diversity

          Attaining  the fish   and  wildlife  .propagation  use  designation  also
 means enhanced  ecological diversity  of River  1  between  Cities A  and  B.
 These benefits  are not quantifiable at the present time but would include more
 diverse flora .and fauna, enhanced diversity of fish species,  and other  related
 elements.  Note:  These benefits will be  listed in the  policy array as "positive
 nonquantifiable" (see Chapter 2  on  intangible benefits), allowing the decision-
 makers to better focus on these questions.   In some cases,  in fact, it  may be
 possible to list specific species that the new use will add or preserve.

     F,   Benefits of Improved Navigation

          Although  achieving  the .designated use  may also  benefit  navigation
 in River  1,  indications  are that  the magnitude of these benefits is negligible.
 Thus,  no attempt will  be made to quantify  them (see Chapter 3 on measuring
 benefits to firms).

     G.   Nonuser/Nonuse  Benefits

          In addition to recreation in or  near the water by current users,  in-
trinsic benefits—option values,  existence values/  and aesthetics--may account
for important benefits  of improved water quality.  Option value refers to the
value current  and potential users place on  having  the option to use the water
 resource  at  some future time. This  value is assigned to the resource because
there is  some uncertainty regarding  its  future availability or regarding future
demand.   Existence  benefits  are  measured  by the value  people place  on ac-
tions  that ensure a  resource  is  (or  will  be)  there,  regardless  of their actual
or potential  use.  This is  sometimes termed vicarious enjoyment or attributed
to a bequest motive.   Aesthetics  refer to beauty that may  be appreciated by
users and/or those who reside  or  travel  nearby.

     Many unresolved  issues  exist  concerning the inclusion and  valuation of
intrinisic  benefits.  For  example, there is not yet any  agreement oh whether
aesthetics should be included in  intrinsic benefits or measured separately or
indeed, whether they  be  measured  at  all.   Thus, intrinsic  benefits  are  in-
cluded in this assessment as  "positive  not quantified"  (see the contingent
valuation  case  study in  Chapter 3, which  highlights an approach for quantify-
ing and monetizing these benefits,)
                                   6-16

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
     H.   Estimate Benefits That Will Accrue In  Future Years

          Assume that  River  1  recreation benefits will remain constant for the
25-year  lifetime used  for  the analysis.   This is  probably a  conservative as-
sumption because, with visit  rates staying the same, any population growth in
the area would  lead to more recreation (unless congestion becomes a problem).
This  growth  is offset,  however, by other important factors such as  the in-
fluence  of  substitute  sites  that  are excluded from  the estimation  models.
Thus, each benefit  estimate  can  be considered to  be a constant stream  over
the project  lifetime.

IV.  Value  the  Detrimental  Effects  Based on Opportunity Costs and Calculate
     Economic  Impacts

     A.   Calculate Increased  Capital and Operating Costs for Model Steel
          Plant

          Step  1

          Determine  availability of data  sources (see  Chapter 4  for details  on
likely sources of cost data).

          Step  2

          Use  the model plant technique  discussed in  Chapter 4 along  with
the wasteload allocation  to  estimate the capital costs of achieving the fish and
wildlife propagation use designation.  A  related study of pollution controls for
steel  plants suggests that  the technologies shown in  Table 6-3  will  be needed
to meet  the regulation.  Two steel  plants correspond  closely with the model
plants;  two are about 3/4 the size  assumed for the plant; and 1  plant is 1-1/4
times larger than the  model plant.   Table 6-4 shows capital  cost estimates for
these plants.
             Table 6-3,   Capital Equipment and Cost for Model Plant
                               to  Meet Regulation
Capital equipment
Wastewater discharge treatment pond
Water integrated flow system
Pretreatment and handling system
5 segments 30" piping
Total
Cost (million $)
1.2
1.6
1.2
2.0
6.0
          Step 3:  Calculate Operating Costs

          Assume  for  the  model  plant  analysis  that  operating  costs  are
roughly  0.05  of  capital costs per year for the life of the plant,  regardless of
the size of the  plant.   Using this estimate  and  the  capital costs from  Table
6r4, calculate:

                                   6-17

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                       Table 6-4.   Estimated  Capital Costs
Number of. plants


Total
2
2
I
5
Percent of model plant
0.75
1.00
1.25
Total estimated capital
cost (million $)
9
12
7.5
28.5
        Operating costs/year = 0.05 x $28.5 million  = $1.4 million/year.

The problem of converting costs  into comparable measures is addressed  in
Chapter 4.

     B.   Calculation of Capital and Operating Costs for City B

          To meet the  requirements of the  designated use of fish and wildlife
propagation, City B will  have to  add an advanced  waste treatment plant for
its  sewage wastes.  Capital  and operating  costs can be  calculated using the
model plant method for advanced  waste treatment (see Chapter 4).

          Step 1

          Determine availability of  data on  costs of advanced treatment  plants
(see Chapter 4 for details on  availability of data on advanced treatment
plants).

          Step 2

          Determine additional capacity needed for the advanced  waste treat-
ment plant.  Assume that the  facility is  to  provide  for.maximum  daily flow
equal to two times expected average daily  flow.  (This  information would come
from a City B  sewer study, for example.)   The additional advanced waste
treatment capacity required is 60 Mgal/d.

          Step 3:

          Table 6-5 shows  the capital cost  estimate  resulting from the model
plant approach.

                 Table 6-5.  Cost of Treatment Plant, City B
               Plant  capacity
Capital cost
                 60 Mgal/d
 $5 million
                                   6-18

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
          Step 4

          Use the  model plant to  estimate  operating  costs.   Based  on other
studies  10  percent of capital  costs  can be  used to represent operating costs
for City B:

              Operating cost =  Capital cost x operating  cost factor

              $500,000/yr   =  5 million    x    0.10.

     C.   Perform Plant  Closure Analysis to  Assess Impact of Regulation
          on  Plant  Operations

          The plant closure test provides a straightforward assessment of the
impact of the regulation following the rules  of thumb referred to in Chapter 2
for plant closures.  There  is  considerable uncertainty involved in actual plant
closure  decisions,  so  this appraisal will give a  benchmark rather than a  com-
.plete determination  of plant  closures.

          Step 1

          Determine data availability (see Chapter  2 and Chapter 4 on finan-
cial data sources that are needed for this test).

          Step 2

          Determine opportunity  cost of capital  and average liquidation value
to the two  steel  companies  that own the five steel plants along  River 1.   Use
these  estimates  in  the following  formula  to  determine the  critical  rate of
return for closures:

          Average liquidation value (m)  x opportunity cost of capital (r)
                                        = critical rate  of return  for closure
          American Steel:     m x r            = critical rate of  return

                              0.50 x 5 percent  =2.5 percent.
         Riverton Steel:
          Step 3
m x r             - critical  rate of return

0.60 x 6 percent  =3.6 percent.
          Compare  critical  rate  of return  with  plant's rate of return  on re-
placement cost with  the  regulation to determine  potential Closure candidates:
                                     6-19

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
         American Steel:  Rate of return  vs.  critical rate of  return

                           5.0 percent    vs.   2.5 percent.



         Riverton Steel;  Rate of return  vs.  critical  rate of return

                           4.8 percent    vs.   3.6 percent.

     Based on this simplified test using rules of thumb,  there are  no closure
impacts.   If closure were indicated, .more detailed calculations  and data would
be  needed to assess the  issue more thoroughly.  Volume  II will address these
more detailed comparisons.

     D.    Perform  Profit Reduction Test

          Another test  to assess the magnitude of the impact of the regulation
on  companies is  the profit  reduction test.   A simplified version of this test is
illustrated below.

          Step 1

          Determine available data (see  Chapter 2).

          Step 2

          Estimate reduction of profits  as a percent of current dollar returns
for the two steel  companies:


          American  Steel:  5 percent reduction in current dollar returns.

          Riverton Steel:  8 percent reduction in current  dollar returns.



These  reductions are both  relatively small  impacts, so no  additional  calcula-
tions are needed.

     E.   Determine Impact  on  Households in City B

          Another  issue in the impact assessment is who bears  the cost of ad-
vanced treatment.  Issues that will need resolution include the following:

          Does  City B  receive  EPA  assistance  for the  advanced  treatment
          plant?   If  so, the citizens  of City B  and all U.S.  taxpayers bear
          the cost impacts.  If not, only residents of City B bear them.

          Will future costs be incurred  by the residents of City B when these
          costs are passed along?

For  purposes of  illustration, no  advanced  treatment assistance from  EPA  is
assumed.
                                    6-20

-------

          Step  1

          Determine  available data  (see  Chapter 2  on municipal waste treat-
 ment cost impacts for more on available data).

          Step  2

          Determine  impact  of increased cost on residents of City B.   Sewage
 costs will  increase an  average of $15 per year  per  household  for residents of
 City  B.

 V,    Compare Total  Benefits and  Costs

      A.   Check for  Less Than Fully Employed  Resources

          Volume  II  will  present  guidelines  on determining  whether  money
 costs overstate  true social costs due to the presence of significant unemployed
 resources.   Assume  the review shows  that  unemployment equals 5  percent in
 both  City A and  City 'B and that a major percentage  of materials comes  from
 outside the  area.  There are no problems with overstating costs  in this case.

      B.   Discounting Benefits and Costs

          This  is a crucial  step  in  the  process of assembling  the benefit-cost
 assessment.  There are several  key steps to. be performed (see  Chapter 2 for
 detailed treatment of these steps).

          Step 1

          Select discount rate  for  converting future  benefits and  costs  into
 present  values.   OMB  guidelines for regulatory impact analyses recommend  a
 real  discount rate of 10  percent.   This  seems  high for a real  rate that  re-
flects  either the  opportunity  cost of capital  or  society's  preferred  rate.
Thus, a range  of rates should  be  used,  with  10 percent on the upper end,
and  the sensitivity of  results  should  be  compared  to the discount rate.  A
social rate of time preference procedure  suggested in  Chapter 2 is  illustrated
in Step  2 below.

          Step 2

          Discount annual monetized  benefits  into present values.

                          Annual Monetized  Benefits
                         Fishing

                         Swimming

                         Near water

                             Total
 million $

      1.55

      0.75

1.5 to 2.4

3.8 to 4.7
                                     6-21

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Since  the  benefit amounts are constant across time periods, to convert mone-
tized annual  benefits into present value equivalents,  use the following formu-
la.  It calculates the present value (P) of a stream of annual benefits  (A) for
n years (assumed project life is 25 years) and interest rate (i):
                                 1 -
                                        1
                         P = A
                                     (1 * i)
                                            n
Table  6-6 shows  the  present values of benefits  calculated with discount rates
ranging from  2 to 10 percent.  Monetized  benefits range from roughly  35  to
92 million 1981  dollars.
                      Table 6-6.   Present Value of  Benefits
               Discount rate
                 (percent) .
Present value
 of benefits
 (million $)
                     2

                     4

                     6

                    10
 74.2 to 91.8

 59.4 to 73.4

 48.6 to 60.1

•34.5 to 42.7
          Step 3

          To  simplify  matters,  assume that all  the capital costs are incurred
in 1981, so that they  are already present values.  Based on the Lind proce-
dure,  these displaced  private  investments  by  the  steel companies  are  multi-
plied  by the shadow price of capital--1.9.  The capital costs  for City B  treat-
ment  plant  are  assumed  to displace consumption (so they do not need adjust-
ing by the shadow price of capitai).

     The  next task is  to translate the  stream of operating costs into a pres-
ent value  equivalent.   The operating  costs  are assumed  to  be displaced ex-
penses  for  the firm and therefore do not require  adjustment  by the shadow
price  of capital.  These expenses  represent displaced consumption and are dis-
counted at  the social  rate of  time preference.   This can be  done with the
same formula as above:
                                      6-22

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                                 1 -
                         P = A
                                     0 * On|  ,
where A  is how a  constant stream of annual operating costs.  Table 6-7 shows
the  present value  of  operating costs calculated with the same range of dis-
count rates used in the benefits calculation.
                  Table 6-7.  Present Value of Operating Costs
            Discount rate
              (percent)
Present value of
operating costs
  (million $)
                  2

                  4

                  6

                 10
      37.1

      29.7

      24.3

      17.2
     Table  6-8 shows the  present  value of total  project  costs,  which range
from 76 to 96  million 1981 dollars.
                         Table 6-8.   Total  Project Costs
Discount
rate
(percent)
2
4
6
10
Capital3
59.2
59.2
59.2
59.2
Operating
37.1
29.7
24.3
17.2
Total
(million $)
96.3
88.9
83.5
76.4
           Private capital costs of the steel companies are  adjusted
           by shadow price of capital.
Note:  Even if  EPA  assistance is received for plant construction,  the society
still  incurs roughly the  same costs  because these  EPA  funds would be  di-
verted from their next  best alternative  use.   There would perhaps  be some
                                    6-23

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
difference because  Federal and local dollars  might have  different forgone op-
portunities,  but the difference is probably minor for purposes of this assess-
ment.
          table 6-9.  Benefits  and Costs of Attaining  Fish and  Wildlife
                          Propagation Use  Designation
     Cost/benefits
   Quantity
  Monetary value
   (million $)
Benefits

  Recreation
    (fishing,  swimming,
    near water)

  Enhanced ecological
    diversity

  User/nonuse—intrinsic
    benefits to users and
    nonusers

Costs

  Capital .and  operating
    (Firms; City B)

  Environmental
Not quantified
Not quantifiable


Not quantified
  for this study
Not relevant


None
    35 to 92
Not monetizable


Not monetized
  for this  study
    76 to 96


         0
VI.  Assess the Plausibility of Total Benefits and Costs

     To .assess the plausibility of benefits and  costs, construct an array and
compare  them.  For example,  Table 6-9 is an array showing both the benefits
and  the  costs of  attaining the fish  and wildlife use  designation.  The  ranges
of monetized benefits  and  monetized  costs  overlap,  nonmonetized benefits  are
positive,  and there are no nonmonetized costs.  The upper end of the  monet-
ized benefits is  slightly  less than  the upper  end of the range of  monetized
costs.   The  lower  end of the monetized benefits is considerably less than  the
lower end of  the  cost range.  Thus,  the  use designation decision would have
to consider whether the intrinsic benefits  and nonquantified, enhanced ecolog-
ical  diversity are greater than the difference between lower benefits and cost
bounds.   When  the  suggested  2 percent social  rate  of time  preference  is
used, the monetized benefits are approximately equal to costs.

     Table 6-10 shows expected benefits from the use designation change and
their distribution  among  area residents and  visitors.  In  some instances, de-
scribing  the distribution of benefits  among more narrowly defined groups may
be desirable.   For example,  assessments involving  a river segment that forms
the boundary between two States  may  require more  precise distribution infor-
mation because the political issues are more  complex  when  more than  one State
is involved.
                                  f 6-24

-------
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
 I
I
                 Table 6-10.   Distribution of  Benefits and Costs
     Benefit/cost
            Distribution
     Recreation
     Enhanced ecological
       diversity
     Nonuse/nonuser
       benefits
     Navigation
     Increased operating and
       capital cost for steel
       plants
     Capital  and operating
       costs  of  advanced
       treatment plant
Users of River 1--primarily recreators
from City A  and City B

To  some extent same as above, but
probably accrues to society as a  whole
including  future generations.

Residents of river  basin.   Visiting
recreators who have  bequest motive
for future generations.

Shippers, boat owners,  purchasers
of materials shipped along  river.
Small magnitude in this  study.

American  and Riverton stockholders
to the extent the costs are not
passed on to customers.  Given the
elasticity of demand for steel and
market shares of these firms,  some
costs will  be passed on to users  of
steel products.  U.S. taxpayers  may
also bear  some costs  because of special
depreciation treatment for pollution
control expenditures.

$15 per user of water and  sewer
service in City B.  This may  be
lower if construction  grant Is  obtained;
then U.S. taxpayers  will share in
the burden.
     To  gain  additional  perspective on the distribution of benefits  and costs,
the breakdown  of recreational benefits by  different income  groups Is shown
below:
                    Income ($)

                 0 to  10,000
                 10,000 to 20,000
                 20,000 to 30,000
                 30,000 to 40,000
                 40,000+
Benefits  (percent)

       15
       25
       35
       20
        5
In this example, 75 percent of the benefits  accrue to households  with  incomes
of less than $30,000/year.  Decisionmakers may view this use change  as more
                                    6-25

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
desirable because of its  larger  share of benefits  going  to low and middle in-
come groups.

     The expected costs  of the  programs also are  arrayed in  Table 6-10.  The
basic economic principle underlying the  distribution of the industrial operating
and  capital cost is  the responsiveness of demand  for the industry's  or firm's
products—the   larger  the  responsiveness  of  quantity  demanded  to  price
changes, the  smaller will  be the ability of the firm or industry to pass along
cost increases  to its customers.  The  stockholders,  workers, and other  re-
source  suppliers to the firm will have to bear the cost  increases that are not
passed  along  through  lower dividends  or reduced wages.  For the steer firms
in this  example, the degree  of  sales  responsiveness  to  price changes will  be
influenced by  their share of the market, the demands for products which  use
the type of steel  produced,  competition  from foreign sources of  steel,-and
competition from substitutes (aluminum).

     The municipal  waste  treatment costs likely will be borne by the  residents
of City B.  Residents  will  include current residents  and future residents who
move,  or are  annexed, into the city's water  or sewer service system.  If the
city  receives  a Federal construction  assistance grant, then  the largest share
of the  capital  costs is distributed  among  a  much larger group—the Federal
taxpayers.
     •*

     This  example  shows how  distribution issues are  integrated with the other
steps in  the  assessment process.  They are described and  listed  but do  not
affect the measurement of either benefits or costs.   Finally,  the  exact nature
of the distribution  descriptions  will  depend on the complexity of the  issues In
the assessment itself.

6.5  SUMMARY

          The  strength of benefit-cost assessment  is its ability to consist-
          ently organize information for a wide range of applications.

          Qualitative assessments,  using  primarily  descriptive  informa-
          tion,  are  sufficient  in many  water quality  applications  because
          of the sizes of potential benefits and costs.

          Defining   the water   quality  action to  be evaluated  in  the
          benefit-cost  assessment determines  the  baseline and suggests
          the  level of complexity in the assessment.

          Translating  effects  of a  water  quality  action  into  beneficial
          outcomes  and costs  requires an  understanding of the linkages
          between each element.

          Valuing beneficial  effects should be based  on  individual's will-
          ingness to pay for them.

          Valuing detrimental  effects  should be  based  on  opportunity
          cost to society of the effects.
                                 6-26

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
Comparing total  benefits  and  total costs  may  involve  qualita-
tive, quantitative,  or monetized information.

Assessing the  plausibilty of benefits and costs may involve test-
ing the  sensitivity  of assumptions made  in  estimating  benefits
and costs, or in selecting a discount rate.

Describing the distribution  of benefits and costs may  provide
valuable data for the decisionmaker.
                           6-27

-------

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
                                 CHAPTER 7


                                REFERENCES
Anderson,  J.  E., 1974,  "A  Note  on  Welfare Surpluses and Gains from Trade
     in  General  Equilibrium,"  American  Economic  Review, Vol.  64,  No.  4,
     September 1974,  pp.  758-62.

Ayres,  R.  V., and  A. V.  Kneese, 1969, "Production and Consumption  Exter-
     nalities," American Economic Review, 59, No.  3, June  1969, 282-97.

Bishop, R. C., and  T. A.  Heberlein,  1979, "Measuring Values of Extra-Market
     Goods:  Are Indirect Measures Biased?"  American Journal of Agricultural
     Economics, Vol.  6, December  1979, pp. 926-30.

Bockstael,  Nancy E., and Kenneth E.  McConnell,  1981, "Theory and Estimation
     of  the Household Production  Function  for Wildlife Recreation," Journal of
     Environmental   Economics   and  Management,  Vol.   8,   September 1981,
     pp. 199-214.

Brookshire,  David S.,  Mark A.  Thayer,  William  D.  Schulze,  and  Ralph C.
     d'Arge,   1982,  "Valuing  Public  Goods:   A  Comparison  of Survey and
     Hedonic Approaches,"  American  Economic  Review, Vol. 72,  March 1982,
     pp. 165-77.

Carlton, D. W.,  1979, "Valuing Market  Benefits  and  Costs in Related Output
     and Input Markets," American Economic Review,  Vol. 69, No. 4, Septem-
     ber 1979, pp. 688-97.

Chemical Engineering, published by McGraw-Hill, New York

Cronin,  Francis J.,  1982,  Valuing Njanmarket Goods Through  Contingent Mar-
     kets,  prepared  for  U.S. Environmental Protection Agency,  Pacific  North~
     west Laboratory, Richland, Washington, September 1982.

Davidson,  P.,  F.  G. Adams, and  J.  Seneca, 1966,  "The  Social Value of Water
     Recreational  Facilities  Resulting  From  an Improvement in Water Quality:
     The Delaware Estuary"  in  Allen V.  Kneese  and Stephen  G.  Smith,  eds.,
     Water  Research,  Johns Hopkins Press for  Resources  for the Future, Inc.,
     1956T         "

Desvousges, William  H.,  V.  Kerry Smith,  and Matthew P.  McGivney, 1983, A
     Comparison  of   Alternative   Approaches  for  Estimating  Recreation  and
     Related Benefits of Water Quality Improvements, report prepared'for U.S.
     Environmental Protection Agency, Research  Triangle Institute,  Research
     Triangle Park, North Carolina, March 1983.
                                  7-1

-------
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
 Deyak, Timothy  A., and  V.  Kerry Smith, 1978,  "Congestion and Participation
     in Outdoor  Recreation:   A  Household  Production Approach,"  Journal  of
     Environmental Ecgn£rnics and Management, Vol. 5, March 1978, pp.  63-80.

 Dwyer, J,  F., J.  R.  Kelly, and  M.  D. Bowes, 1977,  Improved  Procedures for
     Valuation of the  Contribution of Recreation to National  Economic Develop-
     ment,  Urbana-Champaign:  University of Illinois, 1977.

 Engineering News- Record, published  by McGraw-Hill, New York.

 Fox,  I.  K., and O. C.  Herfindahl, 1964, "Attainment of  Efficiency  in Satisfy-
     ing Demands for Water  Resources,"  American Economic  Review, Vol.  54,
     No. 2, May  1964, pp. 198-207.
                                                                     "v
 Freeman,  A.  Myrick,  Ml,  1979,  The  Benefits of Environmental
     Theory and Practice,  Baltimore:  Johns Hopkins Press for  Resources for
     the Future, Inc., 1979.

Guthrie,  K.  M.,  1974,  Process Plant  Estimating,   Evaluation,  and  Control ,
     Solana Beach,  California:  Craftsman Book Company of America,  197T!

Just, Richard  E.,  Darrell L. Hueth,  and Andrew Schmitz, 1982,  Applied  Wel-
     fare Economics arid Public Pqljcy., Englewood Cliffs,  New Jersey:  Prentice
     Hall, 1982.

Larson,  S.,  1981,  Economics .Analysis of Water Quality Improvementsi  Missis-
     sippi  River, Minjiea|jgljs-St.^PauJ  Twin Cities  Area,  Minnesota  Pollution
     Control Agency, Roseville, Minnesota7~T§8T.

Lind,  R. C.,  K. J. Arrow,  G. Corey,  P. Dasgupta,  A. Sen,  t. Stauffer,
     J.  E. Stiglitz, J.  Stockfish,  and  R.  Wilson, 1982,   Discounting for Time
     and Risk in Energy Policy, Baltimore:  Johns Hopkins, 1982.

R. S. Means Company,  Inc., 1981,  Building Construction Cost  Data, Duxbury,
     Massachusetts: R.  S.  Means Company, Inc. , 1981.

Michel,  Robert L.,  "EPA Municipal  Wastewater  Treatment  Plant Operation  and
     Maintenance  Cost   Index,"  U.S.   Environmental   Protection   Agency,
     Washington, D.C., issued  periodically.
                                         /"
Michel,  Robert L.,  "EPA  Sewage Treatment  Plant and Sewer Construction Cost
     Index,  U.S. Environmental  Protection Agency,  Washington,  D.C.,  issued
     periodically.

Mitchell, R.  C., and R.  T. Carson, 1981,  Ah Experiment in Determining Will-
     ingness to  Pay for  National Water Quajjty  I improvements ,  draft  report
     prepared  for  U.S.   Environmental  Protection Agency, Resources for the
     Future, Inc., Washington, D.C., June  1981.

Municipal  Finance Officers  Association  and Peat, Marwick, Mitchell and Co.,
     1982,  Financial Capability Guidebook,  draft,  prepared for U.S. Environ-
     mental Protection Agency,  Washington,  D.C., May 1982.
                                     7-2

-------
I
1
1
i
i
i
i
i
i
i
'—!

i
i
i
i
i
I
i
i
Rae,  Douglas A.,  1981a,  Visibility  Impairment  at Mesa Verde National  Park:
     An  Analysis  of Benefits and  Costs of Controlling Emissions jn_ the Four
     Corners  Area,  prepared  for  the  Electric  Power  Research  Institute,
     Charles River. Associates, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1981.

Rae,  Douglas A.,  1981b,  Benefits  of  Improving  Visibility  at  Great Smoky
     National  Park,  draft  report prepared for Electric Power Research  Insti-
     tute,   Charles  River  Associates,  Cambridge,  Massachusetts,  December
     1981.

Richardson  Engineering Services,  Inc.,  1977,  Process  Plant Construction Esti-
     mating Standards:  The Richardson  Rapid System.  Solana  Be€ch,  Cali-
     fornia:  Richardson Engineering  Services, Inc., 1977.

Rowe,  R. D., and L. G.  Chestnut, 1981,  Visibility Benefits Assessment Guide-
     book,  prepared for  U.S.  Environmental  Protection  Agency,  Abt West,
     Denver, Colorado,  March 1981.                                        X^

Schulze, W. D., R. C.  d'Arge,  and  D. S. Brookshire, 1981, "Valuing Envi-
     ronmental  Commodities:   Some   Recent  Experiments,"  Land  Economics,
     Vol. 57,  No.  2, May 1981, pp. 151-73.

Smith, V. Kerry,  1975, "Travel Cost  Demand Models for Wilderness Recreation:
     A  Problem  of  Non-Nested Hypotheses," Land  Economics,   Vol. 51, May
     1975, pp. 103-11.

U.S.  Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1982, Producer  Prices
     and Price Indexes Data for August 1982, Washington, D.C., 1982.

U.S.  Environmental  Protection Agency,  1976, Areawide Assessment Procedures
     Manual,  Vol. Ill,   EPA-600/9-76-014,  U.S.   Environmental  Protection
     Agency, Cincinnati, Ohio, 1976.

U.S.  Environmental  Protection Agency,  Office of Water Program Operations,
     Office  of Research and  Development, 1980a,  Innovative and Alternative
     technology .Assessment  Manual, LD-53, U.S.  Environmental  Protection
     Agency, Washington, D.C., February 1980.

U.S.  Environmental Protection  Agency, Effluent Guidelines  Division,  1980b,
     Development  Document for Effluent Limitations  Guidelines and  Standards
     for  the  Pulp,  Paper  and the  Builder's  Paper  and  Board Mijjs^ Point
     Source  Categories,  EPA  44Wl-80/025-b,  U.S. Environmental  Protection
     Agency, Washington, D.C., December 1980.

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 1981,  Process Design and  Cost Estimat-
     ing  Algorithms  for the Computer Assisted Procedure for Design and Eval-
     uation  of Wastewater Treatment  Systems (CAPDET),  U.S.  Environmental
     Protection Agency, Washington, D.C., January 1981.

Vaughan, W. J., and C. S. Russell, 1982, "Freshwater Recreational Fishing:
     The  National  Benefits of  Water Pollution  Control,'1  Washington,   D.C.:
     Resources for the Future, Inc.,  November 19§2T
                                     7-3

-------