Tech Memo Home | Publications Home
Introduction
Input-Output Modeling
Components of the NERIOM
Background Data
Model Construction
Impact Estimation
Discussion
References Cited

NOAA Technical Memorandum NMFS-NE-188

Northeast Regional Commercial Fishing Input-Output Model

Scott Steinback and Eric Thunberg
National Marine Fisheries Serv., 166 Water St., Woods Hole, MA 02543

Web version posted May 4, 2006

Citation: Steinback SR, Thunberg EM. 2006. Northeast Regional Fishing Input-Output Model. NOAA Tech Memo NMFS NE 188; 54 p.

Information Quality Act Compliance: In accordance with section 515 of Public Law 106-554, the Northeast Fisheries Science Center completed both technical and policy reviews for this report. These predissemination reviews are on file at the NEFSC Editorial Office.

AcrobatDownload complete PDF/print version

Summary

This manuscript describes several years of work on improving input-output models for use in regulatory analyses of fisheries management actions in the Northeast U.S.  Its primary intent is to provide a description of the partial multiregional input-output modeling approach we developed and to inform peers in how to make the required adaptations to the widely distributed regional input-output modeling system known as IMPLAN Pro.  A hypothetical impact assessment is also conducted to illustrate the types of impacts that can be generated with the model.

1. INTRODUCTION

The economic effects of fishery management policies that alter commercial harvesting levels in a regional economy can be far-reaching.  As commercial harvest levels change ancillary industries that supply the commercial fishing industry with inputs in turn adjust their production levels and expenditure patterns, initiating further rounds of backward linked repercussions in the economy.  Working up the marketing chain, industries such as wholesale seafood dealers and seafood processors may be required to adjust their production levels when the availability of local seafood changes, thereby affecting input requirements from their other suppliers, and triggering a whole series of additional multiplier effects as the economy adapts to the policy action.

The National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA), Executive Order 12866, and National Standard 8 of the Sustainable Fisheries Act require federal regulators to consider the impacts on businesses that are directly and indirectly affected by proposed management actions. The scope of most economic analyses of management actions in the Northeast Region has been limited to analysis of impacts on directly affected businesses and the preparation of benefit/cost analysis which have a national perspective.  While assessments of distributional effects are generally included in a Social Impact Assessment (SIA), the focus of an SIA is on the social implications of a management action on fishermen, fishing families, and social networks in a community.  This means that much of the discussion of the implications of management actions on the larger fishing-related and regional economy is left for vetting in public hearings.

In an attempt to resolve this shortcoming, we have developed a partial multiregional input-output model that is capable of predicting the multiplier effects of proposed fishery management actions in the Northeast.  The model is constructed at the regional level, but it has been designed so that the multiplier effects, expressed in terms of sales by businesses, average annual employment (both full and part-time), and personal income (labor income) can be determined for 24 specific sub-regions within the Northeast.  While a full, disaggregated, multiregional model that explicitly measures the economic connections between all business sectors in 24 different regions is beyond possibility because of data availability, the approach developed here can be described as a partial multiregional model because it explicitly accounts for the interconnections between the fishing-related businesses (commercial harvesters, wholesale seafood dealers, bait suppliers, and seafood processors) in all 24 sub-regions in the Northeast.  The intra and inter-regional seafood linkages are captured through the addition of up to 21 new fishing-related industry sectors in each of the coastal sub-regions.  All of the remaining non-fishing business sectors in the model measure Northeast region-level activity, but an allocation procedure is employed that apportions the estimated region-wide effects for these businesses to the appropriate sub-regions in the model based on the relative importance of a sub-region’s economy to the total Northeast region’s economy.  

The model was constructed using a ready-made regional input-output system called IMPLAN Pro (Minnesota IMPLAN Group, Inc.).  The IMPLAN Pro system consists of software and data that may be purchased from Minnesota IMPLAN Group.  The software provides the mathematical algorithms to estimate I/O models and their resulting multipliers, as well as providing a user interface that makes conducting impact assessments and organizing model outputs easier.  Default data sets available for purchase include county-level data for 509 economic sectors for every county in the U.S.  Data sets for each coastal state from Maine to North Carolina were acquired to construct the I/O model for the Northeast region.

The IMPLAN Pro system has considerable appeal due to its extensive use in practical applications and its readily available support literature.  Further, since the conceptual basis for input-output methodology is quite intuitive, the results of impact assessments can be readily explained to fishery managers and the Public.  This is important because it is our hope that the model’s multiplier effects will be used by managers to compare and contrast the outcomes of proposed management strategies prior to deciding upon a preferred alternative.  The ability to determine how policy-induced changes in sales, income, and employment will be distributed among businesses in 24 different sub-regions in the Northeast should provide regional decision makers with better information to make more informed policy decisions.

The primary purpose of this paper is to provide an overview of the Northeast Region input-output model’s (NERIOM) operations and model outputs.  This includes a comprehensive delineation of the adjustments that were made to the default IMPLAN system, a description of the underlying data, and the impact estimation approach we followed.  A hypothetical impact assessment is also conducted to illustrate the types of impacts that can be generated with the model.  Finally, the advantages and limitations of using the NERIOM approach for assessing the multiplier effects of fishery management actions are considered, along with a discussion of potential model improvements through additional research.


2. INPUT-OUTPUT MODELING

In addition to input-output analysis, there are a variety of other methods available for analyzing the economic impacts of fishery management actions.  These range from simplistic approaches such as economic-base models to sophisticated approaches such as computable general equilibrium models (CGEM) and models that link economic and ecological or biological considerations.  Although these types of models produce total impact estimates that are similar to those generated from input-output models, they either lack the detail and complexity of those created with input-output analysis (i.e., economic-base models) or are more data intensive and generally necessitate even greater sectoral aggregation (i.e., CGEM and economic-ecological models).

In 1973, Professor Wassily Leontief received the Nobel Prize in Economic Science for developing the analytical framework which came to be known as input-output analysis.  Input-output analysis is generally described as a static general equilibrium approach to quantitative economic analysis.  The common fabric underlying all input-output models is a comprehensive accounting system which records the sales and purchases of goods and services among industries (manufacturers), final consumers (households, government, and exports), and resource owners (land, labor, and capital) in a regional economy during a specified time period (usually one year).  As such, input-output models are generally employed to predict the backward linked ripple effects (i.e., multiplier effects) of changes in the economic activity of a particular industrial sector.  For example, a decrease in the output of one industry decreases the demand for output in its supplying industries, and in industries which support the suppliers, and so on.  However, forward linked industries may also experience reductions in output through diminished supply of local production. If one is able to exogenously determine how these forward linked sectors might be impacted, the additional backward linked ripple effects associated with these changes could also be estimated with input-output analysis.  This is discussed further in Section 6 - Impact Estimation

Mathematically, the Leontief input-output approach derives sectoral outputs from exogenously specified final demands as

(1)           Equation 1

where X is a n x 1 column vector denoting output; I is a n x n identity matrix; A is a n x n direct  input coefficient matrix; and is a n x 1 column vector denoting exogenous final demand.  The elements of A () are called direct input coefficients and are denoted as

equation 2

where zij is the level of sales from sector i to sector j; and Xj is the total output of sector j.  The (I-A)-1 matrix is often referred to as the Leontief inverse, comprised of the interdependence coefficients alpha ij (ij)or what are commonly referred to as industry output multipliers.  These multipliers indicate how much the output of each row sector would change if the final demand for sector j’s output changed by one dollar.  In a regional input-output model that treats household income and spending as endogenous1, the column sum of the industry specific output multipliers measures the total direct, indirect, and induced backward linked multiplier effects from each sector of the economy required to satisfy a one dollar change in final demand for sector j’s output.  The direct industry multiplier measures the initial effect of sector j’s one dollar final demand change on itself, which implies a multiplier value of 1.  The total indirect multiplier represents the additional region-wide output changes necessitated by the one dollar change in final demand, and the total induced multiplier measures the economy-wide output effects of changes in household spending generated by the direct and indirect effects.  Total output multipliers are used to estimate the economy-wide backward linked output effect associated with exogenously specified changes in final demand.2

The standard Leontief input-output approach must be modified before it can be applied to fishery management actions, however.  From equation (1) it is clear that the model is designed to ascertain the economy-wide effects of changes in the demand for a product at the final consumption level.  However, fishery management policies act by controlling gross industry output at the point of production, rather than operating to control the sale of outputs in final markets.  For example, fisheries policies are generally implemented to control landings and thus directly affect the production of seafood at the harvesting level.  Therefore, the basic form of equation 1 must be modified to assess the effects of management policies that induce gross changes in industry output. 

To accommodate the problem of handling constraints on sectoral output within an input-output context, a procedure was developed that explicitly transforms the traditional Leontief model into one that is capable of accepting gross output changes as entries as opposed to only final demand changes (Johnson and Kulshreshtha 1982).  This technique, now commonly referred to as a mixed exogenous/endogenous variables model (Miller and Blair 1985, p. 325), was used by Leung and Pooley (2002) in assessing the total economic impacts of a reduction in output of the Hawaii-based longline fishery.  Unfortunately, the number of sectors contained in mixed exogenous/endogenous variables models is generally not sufficient to derive detailed estimates of indirect multiplier effects.  In part, this is because all of the existing ready-made commercial regional input-output models, such as IMPLAN Pro, which provide considerable sectoral detail to trace backward linkages, are based on traditional Leontief techniques and it is not possible to incorporate the modified relationships embodied in the mixed exogenous/endogenous variables approach into these ready-made models (see Steinback 2004).  As a consequence, mixed exogenous/endogenous variables models are usually derived from condensed versions of ready-made models and therefore offer rather limited evaluations of how total estimated impacts are dispersed throughout a particular region.  

In an attempt to provide fishery policymakers with a higher level of sectoral detail than that contained in a mixed exogenous/endogenous variables model, another modification technique which provides the same aggregate solution as the mixed exogenous/endogenous variables model was adopted for this study.  The procedure, first introduced by Tanjuakio, Hastings, and Tytus (1996), can accept gross output changes as entries within a traditional Leontief model by setting the directly impacted sectors’ regional purchase coefficients (RPCs) to zero and then by modeling the changes “as if” they originated from final demand.3  In contrast to the mixed exogenous/endogenous variables model, Tanjuakio, Hastings, and Tytus’ (1996) approach is based on the traditional Leontief relationships shown in equation (1) so it can be incorporated into ready-made input-output models such as IMPLAN Pro.  This is important because ready-made models reduce the cost and complexity of model formulation and the time required to generate impact estimates.4

The ready-made IMPLAN Pro system that was used in this study provides a user-friendly media for customizing input-output models to a specific application, and offers the capability to create custom sectors such as commercial fishing that are not well configured in the default IMPLAN Pro data base.  In fact, constructing an IMPLAN Pro model capable of calculating the multiplier effects of proposed fishery management actions on businesses in 24 different sub-regions in the Northeast required creating many additional fishing-related sectors.  These adjustments are explained in detail in the next section.


3.  COMPONENTS OF THE NORTHEAST REGION INPUT-OUTPUT MODEL (NERIOM)

Fishing Regions in the Northeast U.S.

A distinguishing feature of the NERIOM is its ability to assess the impacts of management alternatives on the entire Northeast Region’s economy and on the economies of 24 specific sub-regions.  The 24 sub-regions represent semi self-sufficient fishing areas that have similar economic networks and fishing-related attributes.  The sub-regional designations were based on several criteria.  First, data on fishing and non-fishing industrial sectors were generally only available at a county-level.  Therefore, the sub-regional impact area designations represent either individual counties or groups of counties within each of the 11 Northeast Region States.  Data obtained from federal Northeast vessel trip reports, Northeast dealer weigh-out slips, Northeast permit applications, and County Business Patterns were used to classify sub-regions that have similar economic networks and fishing-related attributes.  These data provide an indication of regional distribution channels of seafood as it flows from harvesters through dealers and finally on to processors in the Northeast.  The sub-regional designations consist mainly of a coastal county or groups of coastal counties, for these are the counties where the majority of the impacts accrue and where the employees and owners of fishing businesses, seafood dealers, and processors reside.  However, if it were determined that fish are regularly being sold to dealers and processors in adjacent non-coastal counties, the sub-regional designations were expanded to account for these transactions.  There are 23 coastal and one non-coastal sub-region contained in the NERIOM (see Figure 1 and Table 1).

IMPLAN Pro Adjustments

The IMPLAN Pro sector classification system is based on the U.S. Census Bureau’s North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) and contains county-level estimates of business activity for up to 509 industry sectors.  Included in the coding system are four industry sectors that either directly produce seafood or are directly involved in the seafood marketing chain.  These sectors are: animal production including aquaculture (sector 13), fishing (sector 16), seafood product preparation and packaging (sector 71), and wholesale trade (sector 390).  These four sectors, however, are constructed from aggregate industrial sector level data which do not distinguish businesses of different types and sizes.  For example, all commercial fishing harvesters, regardless of gear type or size, are included in one aggregate “catch-all” fishing sector (sector 16).  This level of aggregation is too gross for conducting impact assessments of fishery management actions on specific fisheries or gear types.  Furthermore, since businesses that produce similar types of products or services are generally pooled into a single IMPLAN Pro sector, the underlying data may not accurately portray the establishments of interest.  For instance, businesses engaged in the wholesale distribution of seafood comprise only a small portion of the wholesale activity included in the single default “wholesale trade sector”.  The production functions, tradeflows, and value-added estimates associated with seafood wholesalers that deal with a perishable product may be different from those of wholesalers that distribute other durable or nondurable goods.  Therefore, the fishing-related sectoral designations and underlying data must be refined before IMPLAN Pro can be used to describe the economic activity associated with fishery management actions.

To the extent that the businesses most impacted by fishery management actions are  commercial fishing, wholesale distribution of seafood, and seafood processing, our refinements focused on improving on the aggregate information contained in IMPLAN Pro sectors 16 (fishing), 390, (wholesale trade), and 71 (seafood product preparation and packaging).  Since the National Marine Fisheries Service (NMFS) is not directly responsible for managing the activities associated with aquaculture establishments no adjustments were made to sector 13 (animal production).

We began by deleting IMPLAN Pro’s single commercial fishing sector and adding new harvesting sectors based on gear type and vessel size class.  Consideration was given to classifying sectors according to primary species landed, but since management regulations often target specific gear sectors or vessels of a given size class it was necessary to incorporate these characteristics into the NERIOM.  Further, the number of modifications necessary to construct a species-specific model would have been much larger than was necessary to develop gear-based sectors.  Commercial fishing businesses were grouped into 18 distinct gear sectors in 22 of the 23 coastal county sub-regions.  No harvesting sectors were added for the North Carolina north sub-region or for inshore and offshore lobster vessels in the North Carolina central sub-region.  An IMPLAN Pro model is limited to 1,000 industry sectors and this constraint would have been exceeded after adding all of the new harvesting sectors and the remaining fisheries-related sectors to be discussed below.  Therefore, since there were no recording landings in the North Carolina north sub-region in 2001 (the base year of the NERIOM) nor for the North Carolina central inshore and offshore lobster harvesting sectors in 2001, these industries were excluded from the model.  A total of 394 new harvesting sectors were added to the NERIOM.  Table 2 delineates all of the new sectors that were added to the default IMPLAN Pro model.  The data used in the construction of the fisheries-related sectors are discussed in the next section. Additional modifications included separating the wholesale seafood dealer component from the default wholesale trade sector and adding 23 new wholesale seafood dealer sectors (one for each coastal sub-region).  Since seafood also passes through fish exchanges/auctions in four sub-regions in New England a fish exchange sector was created in each of these sub-regions (Lower Mid-Coast Maine, Massachusetts North Shore, Massachusetts Boston Area, and Massachusetts New Bedford Coast).5  Purchases of bait by longline, hand gear, and lobster vessels were accounted for by assigning the purchases directly to 23 new midwater trawl bait supplying sectors and 23 medium bottom trawl bait supplying sectors (one in each coastal sub-region).  In the Northeast, midwater and bottom trawls land the majority of the species used as bait by the longline, handgear, and lobster sectors.  Lastly, we removed the default seafood processing sector (sector 71) and added a sub-regional processing sector in each of the 23 coastal sub-regions.     

Product Flow Assumptions

The distribution patterns of seafood among harvesters, wholesalers, processors, and final demand establishments in the Northeast U.S. are complex.  Product flow patterns are influenced by product type, market demand (both domestic and foreign), location of buyers and sellers, sales agreements/contracts between buyers and sellers, management regulations, and a host of other immeasurable factors that present challenges to modeling.  In a regional input-output model each successive level of sale among seafood industry establishments adds value to the product, thereby generating additional economic impacts.  Thus, it is important to account for the origin and destination of purchases and sales that will be impacted (either directly or indirectly) by management regulations.

Unfortunately, limited available data on this complicated product flow within the Northeast region called for some simplifying assumptions.  In the NERIOM, harvesters are assumed to sell all of their output to wholesale dealers via direct sales or through fish exchanges/auctions (see Figure 2).  Since federally permitted harvesters are required to sell to establishments that hold a valid federal dealer permit, this assumption is reasonable.  For state water fisheries or where some vessels may engage in direct sales to final consumers this assumption is tenable.  Wholesale dealers, in turn, are then assumed to sell their output to final consumers, intermediate demand industries (including seafood processors) and to businesses located outside of the Northeast region.  However, due to the number of available seafood substitutes at the retail level, the impacts of most fishery management actions on final consumers and intermediate demand industries other than seafood processors are likely to be negligible.  Therefore, impacts that may accrue beyond the processor level are not incorporated in the NERIOM (see Section 7 for more detail).


4.  BACKGROUND DATA

Sales (Output)

Estimates of sales by the harvesting sectors (i.e., ex-vessel revenues) were derived from 2001 Northeast dealer weigh-out slips for each sub-region.  In cases where the value of landings for a given state was not assigned to a county, sales were prorated to each sub-region within the state based on calculated revenue shares by gear sector and sub-region for data that was assignable.

Total wholesale seafood dealer sales in each sub-region were derived from 2002 Economic Census data (U.S. Census Bureau 2004), 2001 County Business Patterns data (U.S. Census Bureau 2003) and the average 2001 Fulton Market margin.  The Economic Census estimates of National wholesale seafood dealer sales and employment were used to calculate a value for average sales per employee.  This value was then multiplied by the County Business Patterns estimates of number of employees in each sub-region to obtain sales estimates for the sub-regions.  Note that in the NERIOM the wholesale seafood dealer sectors are treated as margin sectors.  That is, the value of sales excludes the “cost of goods sold.”  In so doing, the sales estimate for a margin sector includes only the value added to the product being sold (i.e., total value of sales less the cost of the purchased raw material).  Therefore, the sub-regional sales estimates were multiplied by the average Fulton Market mark-up (i.e., margin) in 2001 (40%).

Fish exchange/auction houses are also required to hold a valid federal dealer permit so it was possible to obtain sales estimates for seafood that passed through these establishments from the 2001 Northeast dealer weigh-out data.  Fish exchange/auction houses were also treated as margin sectors in the NERIOM, however, so the weigh-out data had to be refined so that it represented only the value added by the auction houses.  Value added by auction houses is generally associated with a small per-pound commission to unload, sort, ice, and display the seafood.  The fees cover employee expenses and operating costs, which, in turn, generate additional economic impacts in the Northeast region.  Average handling fees vary slightly across species and auction houses, but were assumed to be 11 cents per pound (7 cents paid by the boat and 4 cents by the buyer (R. Ciulla, co-manager Gloucester Seafood Display Auction, personal communication).  Given handling fees, the sales estimates (i.e., the value of production) for the 4 fish exchange sectors were calculated by first dividing the average handling fee by the average annual price per pound of seafood sold at each exchange in 2001, and then multiplying the result by the total annual value of seafood sold at each exchange.

IMPLAN Pro default values for sector 17 (seafood product preparation and packaging) in each of the 23 coastal sub-regions were used to determine the value of the processing sectors’ sales.  These values were obtained by constructing separate default IMPLAN Pro models for each of the 23 coastal sub-regions and then incorporating the resulting 23 processor sales values into the NERIOM.

Employment

Employment estimates for fishermen are typically not compiled according to type of harvesting gear.  In fact, because self-employed fishermen are generally not included in U.S. labor statistics, there is often a great deal of uncertainty even in aggregate estimates of commercial fishing employment.  However, all federally permitted harvesters in the Northeast are required to fill out vessel trip reports in which  they indicate the type of gear employed and the number of crew (including captain) that participated on each trip.  This data provided the basis for calculating the majority of the harvesting sector employment estimates in each sub-region.  Limited Northeast vessel trip reports were available for the hand gear trips, dive gear trips, and ocean quahog dredge gear trips, so another method for estimating employment was employed for those gear sectors.  Employment calculations for both methods are shown below.

The steps used to calculate employment from vessel trip reports (VTR) were as follows:

(1)   Identify a gear sector for all VTR trips in each sub-region;
(2)   Calculate the average number of crew by vessel for all vessels that participated in a gear sector in each sub-region;
(3)   Sum total annual value of landings by vessel for all vessels that participated in a gear sector in each sub-region;
(4)   Sum total annual value by gear sector and sub-region;
(5)   Sum average crew by gear sector and sub-region;
(6)   Calculate the value/labor ratio by dividing the result of step 4 by the result of step 5; and
(7)   Divide the value/labor ratio from step 6 into the total value of production (i.e., sales values discussed above) by gear sector and sub-region to obtain employment estimates. 

Employment numbers for the hand gear sectors, dive gear sectors, and ocean quahog dredge gear sectors were estimated by dividing the sectoral production values (sales values) by IMPLAN Pro’s default value/labor ratios for sector 16 (Fishing) in each sub-region.  The value/labor ratios were obtained by creating 23 default sub-regional IMPLAN Pro models.

Wholesale seafood dealer employment estimates were obtained from 2001 County Business Patterns Data (NAICS sector 42246; U.S. Census Bureau 2003).  Employment values for counties with suppressed seafood dealer data were estimated by multiplying the average state-level employment per establishment by the total establishments contained in the county (County Business Patterns provides estimates of number of establishments even if employment data is suppressed).

Employment estimates for the four fish exchange/auction sectors were obtained by making several simplifying assumptions as follows:

(1)   Average earnings per employee in each of the four sub-regions where the fish exchange/auction sectors are located were assumed to be equal to the wholesale seafood dealer average earnings values in those sub-regions.
(2)   Calculate total employee earnings for each fish exchange/auction sector by multiplying the sectoral production values by the percent of total value that is used to pay employee earnings (the derivation of these employee compensation percentages is described in the next section).
(3)   Divide total employee earnings for each fish exchange/auction sector by the average earnings per employee from step 1 to obtain employment estimates.     

Cost-Earnings

The validity of impact estimates generated by input-output models depends to a large degree on the underlying industry cost data, and in identifying which combination of IMPLAN Pro sectors is most likely to represent the distribution of these costs.  In the development of the NERIOM, a significant effort was made to incorporate the best available cost and earnings data for harvesters, wholesale dealers, fish exchanges/auctions, and seafood processors.  Cost and earnings data are the heart of an input-output model because they are used to construct production functions that link the purchasing activities of a particular sector to all other sectors in the model.  This section describes the origin of these data and explains how the production functions were created. 

We also extended considerable effort in developing a bridge that was used to allocate each industry expenditure item to its appropriate IMPLAN Pro sector or sectors.  The description of this bridge is quite lengthy, however, so it was placed in Appendix A.  Nonetheless, readers are encouraged to review the bridging process shown in Appendix A because input-output model results are particularly sensitive to how industry expenditures are distributed among sectors.

Cost and earnings estimates for harvesters were derived from Northeast Observer data, Northeast Dealer data, and surveys of specific gear sectors in the Northeast.  A detailed description of these data sources by gear type is provided below and a summary is shown in Table 3.

Inshore and Offshore Lobster Trap

As part of a larger project to develop a simulation model of the lobster fishery researchers at the University of Rhode Island conducted a series of focus groups with lobster vessel owners (Anonymous, 1995).  These focus groups were conducted in selected ports throughout New England and were conducted with both inshore and offshore participants.  In addition to gathering data on trap management and notable changes in the fishery, the researchers collected information on operating costs, fixed costs, and crew remuneration.  Since these data were originally collected in 1993-1994 the cost estimates were adjusted to 2001 dollars using IMPLAN Pro price deflators. 

Linear production functions for offshore lobster, Northern inshore lobster (Maine and New Hampshire) and Southern inshore lobster (Massachusetts southward) were then developed by calculating the proportion of total costs (including payments to crew and profits) each expenditure item represented (Table 4).  Before these production functions could be incorporated into the NERIOM, however, several of the proportions (i.e., absorption coefficients) had to be adjusted for wholesale and retail trade margins.  Commodities and services purchased directly from manufacturers (i.e., mooring fees, repair and maintenance services, permit fees, etc.) have no transportation, wholesale, or retail markups so no adjustments were made to these absorption coefficients (Table 4).  However, expenditures for commodities obtained from wholesalers or retailers (i.e., groceries, fuel, trip supplies, etc.) must be subdivided into the portion going to the retailer, wholesaler, transportation industries, and the manufacturer.  The IMPLAN Pro system provides margin tables for each manufactured commodity that is purchased at the wholesale and retail level, to determine how a dollars worth of consumer expenditures is distributed among the manufacturing, wholesale, transportation, and retail industries that contribute to its production and distribution.  These margin tables were used to distribute the absorption coefficients in Table 4 that pertained to commodities purchased from wholesalers or retailers, into the amount paid to the retailer, wholesaler, transportation industries, and the manufacturer.  The adjusted values were then incorporated into the production functions shown in Table 4 and entered into the NERIOM.  The adjusted production functions were too large to present in this document, but the margined proportions used to adjust the absorption coefficients shown in Table 4 are contained in Appendix A.

Bottom Trawl

Cost and earnings data for the small (< 50 feet), medium (50 to 70 feet), and large (> 70 feet) bottom trawl vessels were obtained from three sources.  Average variable cost estimates (e.g., ice, fuel, oil, water, food, bait, and supplies) were obtained through the Northeast Fisheries Science Center’s sea sampling program.  These data are collected for all commercial fishing trips that carry onboard observers and represent the best available trip-level data for many fisheries.  Northeast observer data from 2003 were used to estimate average trip-level expenditures because the coverage in 2003 was considerably higher than in 2001.  IMPLAN Pro’s deflators, which are derived from the Bureau of Labor Statistics Growth Model, were used to adjust these average values to their 2001 equivalent.

All fixed cost expenditures were derived from studies conducted by researchers at the University of Rhode Island (URI).  The data for the studies were collected from mail surveys of Northeast fishing vessels whose primary gear was an otter trawl.  Results of the studies were published in two reports: one for small trawlers (Lallemand et al. 1998) and one for large trawlers (Lallemand et al. 1999).  Small trawlers were defined as vessels of 65 feet or less and large trawlers consisted of all vessels greater than 65 feet.  These length categories are different than those contained in the NERIOM, however, so we obtained access to the raw survey data and recalculated average fixed cost estimates for the three categories of vessels contained in our model (i.e., small, medium, and large trawlers).  All data were then adjusted to their 2001 equivalent using IMPLAN Pro inflators.

Average gross stock estimates were derived from 2001 Northeast dealer data and pertained only to those vessels that were surveyed in the URI reports.  In combination with average crew and vessel remuneration percentages obtained from the raw URI survey data, the gross stock estimates were used to calculate the value of crew payments (employee compensation) and boat profits (proprietary income).  Linear production functions for the three categories of bottom trawl vessels could then be developed by calculating the proportion of total costs (including payments to crew and profits) each expenditure item represented (Table 4).  Appendix A contains the adjustments made for commodities purchased at the wholesale or retail level.

Scallop Dredge

The cost and earnings data for scallop dredge vessels were obtained from a study conducted by researchers at the University of Massachusetts Dartmouth (see Georgianna, Cass, and Amaral 1999).  The study design involved a mail survey to all vessels that held a federal sea scallop permit in the Northeast in 1997.  The researchers categorized the data by small (< 50 feet), medium (50 to 70 feet), and large (> 70 feet) vessels, so the average variable and fixed cost estimates published in the report were directly applicable to the vessel size classifications used for scallop vessels in the NERIOM.  Average earnings estimates for crewmen, captains, and vessel owners were also determined from the survey data for each of the vessel size categories.  After all of the average expenditures were obtained (including payments to crew and profits) linear production functions were created to be incorporated into the NERIOM (Table 4). Appendix A contains the adjustments made for commodities purchased at the wholesale or retail level. 

Surfclam, Ocean Quahog Dredge

Cost and earnings data for this gear sector were unavailable so the production function created for the medium scallop dredge sector was used a placeholder until estimates for clam dredge vessels are obtained. 

Sink Gillnet

Variable costs for sink gillnet vessels were derived from 2003 Northeast observer data and adjusted to their 2001 equivalent using IMPLAN Pro deflators.  The availability of fixed costs and earnings data for these vessels was quite limited, however, so values that pertained to bottom longline vessels (described below) were used as placeholders until these data are collected.  Fishing costs for bottom longline vessels are likely to be similar to vessels fishing with sink gillnets because they generally operate in the same manner.  Nonetheless, the production function created for sink gillnet vessels was derived from a combination of observer data and bottom longline proxy data (see Table 4).  Appendix A contains the adjustments made for commodities purchased at the wholesale or retail level.

Diving Gear

The southern inshore lobster production function was used as a proxy to describe the purchasing activities of the diving gear sectors until cost and earnings estimates for vessels fishing with this gear are obtained.  Note that purchases unique to the lobster fishery such as bait and traps were excluded from the dive gear production function.  Expenditures for these items were reallocated to the remaining cost categories according to the relative shares contained in the production function.

Midwater Trawl

Northeast observer coverage for this fishery is quite limited and information on fixed costs and earnings could not be found for vessels that fish with midwater trawls.  Therefore, the production function created for the medium bottom trawl fishery was used as a placeholder until these data become available. 

Fish Pots and Traps

The operating characteristics of inshore lobster fishing are very similar to fishing with fish pots and traps.  Since specific cost and earnings data for this gear sector could not be located, the production function created for southern inshore lobster fishing was used to represent the purchasing activities associated with the fish pots and traps sectors in the NERIOM.

Bottom Longline

Average variable cost estimates were generated with data obtained from the Northeast observer program in 2003.  IMPLAN Pro deflators were used to estimate 2001 equivalent values.  Data collected by researchers at the University of Massachusetts Dartmouth, for a study of longline vessel owners in the Northeast in 1997, were used to calculate average fixed costs and value-added estimates (see Georgianna and Cass 1998).  After these estimates were adjusted to 2001 values, they were combined with the Northeast observer variable cost data and linear production functions were created by calculating the proportion of total costs attributable to each expenditure item (Table 4). Appendix A contains the adjustments made for commodities purchased at the wholesale or retail level.

Other Mobile Gear

This gear sector includes all mobile gear except trawls and dredges.  Vessels fishing with purse seines, scottish seines, danish seines, stop seines, bag nets, lift nets, shrimp beam trawls, stop nets, runaround gillnets, and trammel nets were classified as other mobile gear in the NERIOM.  The production function created for medium bottom trawls was used to represent the purchasing activities of these other mobile gear sectors.

Other Fixed Gear

Landings from fixed gears such as pound nets, weirs, harpoons, fyke nets, pelagic longlines, box traps, and drift/anchor gillnets were combined into an other fixed gear sector.  The sink gillnet production function was used to characterize industry purchases for these gear types. 

Hand Gear

Cost and earnings data for vessels fishing with hand gear were estimated from surveys of jig and pole vessel owners that fished for groundfish in New England in 1997 (see Georgianna, Cass, and Brough 1998).  IMPLAN Pro’s inflators were used to adjust mean expenditure values to their 2001 equivalent.  The predominant gear in this sector is hand lines, but also includes dip nets, cast nets, tongs and grabs, oyster rakes, picks, shovels, forks, hoes, and common and long seines.  Linear production functions were also generated for these gears by calculating the proportion of total costs each expenditure item represented (Table 4).  Appendix A contains the adjustments made for commodities purchased at the wholesale or retail level.

Small Dredge

This sector is comprised of oyster, clam, crab, conch, mussel, and urchin dredge gear.  The production function created for small scallop dredges was used to represent the purchasing activities of these dredge sectors.

Wholesale Seafood Dealers

A production function developed for wholesale seafood dealers in the Mid-Atlantic region by Kirkley, Ryan, and Duberg (2004) was used to characterize the purchasing behavior of the 23 wholesale seafood sectors in the NERIOM (Table 5).  As previously mentioned, the wholesale seafood dealer sectors are treated as margin sectors so the production function does not include the cost of purchasing seafood from the commercial fishing sectors.  Appendix A contains the adjustments made to the production function for commodities purchased at the wholesale or retail level.

Fish Exchange/Auctions

Expenditures by the 4 fish exchange/auction sectors contained in the NERIOM were modeled with a production function developed by Kirkley, Ryan, and Duberg (2004) for Fulton Fish Market in New York (Table 5).  The data utilized in their report were obtained from TechLaw, Inc. (2001) and represent the operating costs associated with the provision of services offered by the Fulton Market.  These services are similar to those offered by the fish exchange/auction houses in the NERIOM.  See Appendix A for the adjustments made to the production function for commodities purchased at the wholesale or retail level.

Seafood Processors

The default IMPLAN Pro production functions for Sector 71 Seafood Product Preparation and Packaging, in the 23 coastal sub-regions, were used to allocate purchases to their appropriate IMPLAN Pro sectors in the NERIOM.  The default sub-regional production functions were too large to include in this document.

Exports

Foreign trade data by species and product type were obtained from the Fisheries Statistics and Economics Division of the National Marine Fisheries Service (NMFS).  These data provide information on trade (value and pounds) through specific U.S. customs districts such as New England and the Mid-Atlantic regions.  The procedures used to incorporate these trade data into the NERIOM are delineated in the next section.


5.  MODEL CONSTRUCTION

An IMPLAN Pro model consists of more than 60 underlying Microsoft Access tables (Table 6).  These tables can be grouped into four general categories.  The tables in the first category contain unique code numbers for industries, commodities, margins, value-added sectors, household expenditure groups, institutions, transfer payments, and trade.  Tables in the second category contain raw input data used in the impact assessment portion of the program.  Default model building information about the study area and model specs are contained in the third category of tables; and the remaining tables contain report data that are created during the model construction stage, the impact analysis stage, and for viewing final impact runs.  In constructing the NERIOM, changes were made to the majority of the Access tables in the first and second categories and a few of the Access tables in the fourth category (modified Access tables are indicated with an * in Table 6).

The modification procedure generally consisted of exporting the data contained in the relevant Microsoft Access tables to Microsoft Excel, adding new data, and then importing the modified tables back into Microsoft Access.  A brief summary of the modification procedure is shown in Table 7, and the detailed steps involved in building the Northeast Region input-output model are presented below.  This section also includes a description of the adjustments made to each of the individual Microsoft Access tables.

Model Construction Steps

Step 1 -- A default Northeast Region input-output model with a set of estimated multipliers was first created by opening the IMPLAN Pro software, importing the default 2001 IMPLAN data for all of the counties in Table 1, and then constructing a default IMPLAN model along with a set of estimated multipliers.

Step 2 -- The default model was then opened using Microsoft Access 2000.  IMPLAN  Pro data bases require this version of Access.

Step 3 -- The three US tables and the Observed RPCs table were then deleted.  This step was necessary because all IMPLAN Pro models share the following five tables (as indicated by black arrows to the left of the tables when the model is opened in Access):

Deletion of these tables “breaks” the link so that any subsequent changes will not affect other IMPLAN models.  No changes were made to the Margin Codes table so it was not necessary to remove the link to this table.

Step 4 -- The deleted tables (the three US tables and the Observed RPCs table) were then replaced with the same tables contained in the 2001 IMPLAN Pro structural matrix file 01NAT509.IMS through the import feature in Access.

Step 5 -- In Access, the default data in the 16 tables that needed to be modified were exported to Excel.  Note that since the US Absorption table consisted of over 80,000 rows of data, it was necessary to create two Excel tables to house this information since Excel has a capacity of 65,536 rows.

Step 6 -- All of the default data in the 16 tables to be modified were deleted.  The table layout including column and table names was not changed so that the updated data could be imported back into the original Access file structure.

Step 7 -- Data in these 16 tables were modified to better reflect the sectoral linkages among fisheries-related industries.  Consistent with Step 6, the variable names and record formats were maintained so that the files were compatible with the original Access file structure.

Step 8 -- Once all 16 data files had been modified they were imported into Access.  An append query in Access was used to combine the two US Absorption Excel files into one US Absorption table.

Step 9 -- The modified model was then opened in IMPLAN Pro, the model was reconstructed and multipliers were re-estimated.  This step was necessary because IMPLAN Pro is not capable of recognizing the direct changes made to the underlying Access tables, so the model must be reconstructed to use the updated data.

IMPLAN Pro Table Adjustments

The following provides a more detailed discussion of modifications to certain Access tables.

Industry/Commodity Codes

This table contains unique code numbers for industries and commodities.  Industries and commodities share the same name and number in an IMPLAN Pro model.  Modifications began by removing the default commercial fishing sector (IMPLAN sector number 16) and adding 394 new harvesting sectors to the model (sectors 510-903 in Table 2).  These industry sectors designate different commercial fishing gear and vessel length categories in each of the sub-regions in the Northeast.

Additional changes included adding 23 wholesale seafood dealer sectors (sector’s 904-926 in Table 2), 4 fish exchange sectors (sector’s 927-930 in Table 2), 23 midwater trawl bait supplying sectors, and 23 medium bottom trawl bait supplying sectors (sectors’s 931-976 in Table 2).  Finally, we removed the default seafood processing sector (IMPLAN sector number 71) and added 23 sub-regional processing sectors (sector’s 977 - 999 in Table 2).

Type Codes

The Type Codes table contains coding information on all transaction types in the data sets.  For this table, we added the 490 industry/commodity code designations as assigned above and the associated 490 SAM Commodity codes.  Transaction codes associated with Factors, Households, Institutions, Transfers, Employment, Output, and Trade remained the same.

US Absorption

This table contains the United States absorption matrix which, in input-output terminology, is the coefficient form of the use table.  The default 2001 table contains 80,285 rows of data that show the proportions of commodities each industry uses in its production process (i.e., its production function).  We removed the 213 rows of data contained in the production functions for the default commercial fishing sector (sector 16) and the default seafood processing sector (sector 71), and then added 55,425 rows of data that contained the production functions of each of the 490 fisheries-related sectors that were added to the model.

Sectors that purchase commodities from the default commercial fishing sector (i.e., seafood) and the default seafood processing sector required adjustments to their production functions, since these two default sectors were removed from the Northeast Region input-output model.  Adjustments were made by first identifying the industries that purchase seafood from these sectors.  The commodity balance sheet report option in IMPLAN Pro provides information on all industry sectors that purchase from a particular sector.  Using this option, we were able to identify the 11 industry sectors that purchase seafood from the default commercial fishing sector, and the 27 industries that purchase from the default seafood processing sector in the 2001 data (Table 8 and Table 9).  However, in our Northeast Region model wholesale seafood dealers are assumed to purchase 100% of the commercial fishing output.  Thus, it was necessary to change the assignment of seafood purchases for the 11 industry sectors that purchase commercial fishing output.  We assumed that 7 of the 11 sectors would purchase seafood from seafood processors and the remaining 4 would purchase from wholesale seafood dealers (see Table 8).

This reassignment strategy, however, entailed an additional step because the Northeast Region model includes 23 sub-regional wholesale seafood dealer sectors and 23 sub-regional seafood processing sectors.   A method had to be developed to determine from whom of the sub-regional dealers and processors the industries in Table 8 and Table 9 would purchase their seafood.  At the suggestion of the software vendor, we decided to allocate purchases according to output proportions in each sub-region.  In other words, we used the sub-regional shares of total wholesale seafood dealer output and seafood processing output in the Northeast Region to allocate purchases.  These shares were then multiplied by the default commercial fishing sector’s and/or the default seafood processing sector’s gross absorption coefficient contained in the production functions of each of the sectors shown in Table 8 and Table 9.  The resulting vector of absorption coefficients was then inserted into the US Absorption Table in place of the default values for each of the sectors shown in Table 8 and Table 9.  Note that the sum of the values contained in the vector of absorption coefficients must sum exactly to the absorption coefficient contained in the default data or the model will not build correctly.

US Absorption Totals

The US Absorption Totals table contains the sum of the absorption coefficients for each industry sector.  We removed the default commercial fishing sector’s total absorption coefficient and the default seafood processing sector’s total absorption coefficient, and then added the appropriate absorption coefficients for the 490 new sectors in the Northeast Region model.  The sum of the coefficients from each sector in the US Absorption table must match the coefficients in the US Absorption Totals table.

US Byproducts

This table contains US estimates of the proportions of each commodity an industry produces.  In input-output terminology it is the coefficient form of the “make” table derived by dividing each element by the make table row totals.  Industries often produce more than one commodity.  Commodities other than primary commodities are called secondary commodities or byproducts.  For this table, we first examined if any of the 509 default industry sectors produced commercial fishing seafood or processed seafood as a byproduct.  The commodity balance sheet report option in IMPLAN Pro provides information on commodity production by all industries.  From this report we found that no other industries produced commercial fishing seafood as a byproduct in the 2001 data.  However, there were three industries (Frozen food manufacturing, Fruit and vegetable canning and drying, and Meat processed from carcasses) that produced processed seafood as a byproduct.  If we allowed these sectors to produce processed seafood as a byproduct, the model would not construct properly because the default seafood processing sector was removed from the model.  Therefore, we removed the proportion associated with processed seafood for these three sectors and added it to their primary commodity share, so that the sum of each sector’s byproducts coefficients remained equal to one.  The byproducts coefficients, which include the primary commodity share coefficient, must sum to one for each sector in the model in order for the model to construct properly.

We also assumed that each of the 490 new sectors that were added to the model would produce only primary commodities.  Thus, we added a single record to the US Byproducts table for each of the 490 new sectors and set each sector’s primary commodity share coefficient to one.

SACommodity Sales

This table shows sales of commodities by households and institutions in the study area.  There were no sales of seafood by households in the default data so no changes were made to the commodity sales rows for the nine household expenditure sectors (i.e., Type Codes 10001 - 10009).  There were also no institutional sales of raw harvested seafood or processed seafood. However, zeros are entered into the commodity sales field when no sales are present so we had to remove the records that pointed to these commodity codes in the default institutional sales data.  In addition, since we assumed that there are no institutional sales of commodities produced by the 490 new industries that were added to the model, rows with zeros in the commodity sales field were inserted into the table.

We also removed inventory additions (Type Code 14002) that existed in the default data for the seafood processing sector (Sector 71) because we eliminated this sector from the Northeast Region model.  Sales estimates for the 23 new sub-regional seafood processing sectors in the model were estimated by first constructing 23 separate sub-regional IMPLAN Pro models to obtain the default inventory seafood processing values in each sub-region, and then assigning them to the 23 sub-regional seafood processing commodity codes in the SA Commodity Sales table.

SAEmployment

The SAEmployment table delineates average annual jobs for each industry in the study area.  Jobs are measured in terms of both full-time and part-time workers combined.  For this table, we removed the employment estimates for the default commercial fishing sector (Sector 16) and the default seafood processing sector (Sector 71), and then inserted our employment estimates for the 490 new sectors.

SAFinal Demands

The final demand table consists of purchases of commodities for final consumption by households and institutions.  Several modifications were made to this table.  The first step entailed removing final demands associated with the default commercial fishing sector and the default seafood processing sector for all nine of the household expenditure type codes and for all of the institution type codes.  We then used these default values in combination with output data and the dealer transaction matrix (see Section 6) to estimate final demands by type codes for the new harvesting sectors, seafood dealer sectors, and seafood processing sectors.

Final demands for each of the 394 new harvesting sectors were estimated by first calculating the proportion of a sector’s output to the total output across all 394 sectors, and then multiplying this proportion by each default commercial fishing sector’s (Sector 16) final demand value contained in a Northeast Region-level model across type codes.

Final demands at the wholesale seafood dealer level were more difficult to calculate because the wholesale seafood dealer sector is lumped into in an all-encompassing wholesale trade sector in an IMPLAN Pro model.  Thus, there were no default final demand values specifically for seafood purchased at the wholesale level to use as a benchmark in our new model.  Therefore, we used the average 2001 wholesale seafood mark-up from Fulton fish market (40%) in combination with the dealer transaction matrix to determine final demands by type code for all 23 wholesale seafood dealers in the model.  Assuming that all commercially landed seafood flows through wholesale dealers, we first divided the commercial fishing final demand sales calculated above by 0.4 to calculate the wholesale dealer final demand sales associated with each of the 394 new harvesting sectors.  We then multiplied these values by the proportions contained in the dealer transaction matrix to determine final demand sales by wholesale dealer and type code associated with each new harvesting sector.  Lastly, we summed the final demand sales across harvesting sectors for each wholesale dealer by type code.  The resulting final demand vector contained final demand sales for all 23 wholesale seafood dealers by type code and was incorporated into the SAFinal Demands table.  These final demands were also subtracted from the default wholesale trade final demand values since they were reassigned to 23 new sectors in our model.

Last, final demands for the 23 seafood processing sectors were calculated in the same manner as the harvesting sector’s final demands.  The proportion of a sector’s output to the total output across all 23 sectors was multiplied by each default seafood processing sector’s (Sector 71) final demand value contained in a Northeast Region-level model across type codes.

SAForeign Exports

The SAForeign Exports table shows demands made for goods and services by consumers and industries outside the US.  For this table, we removed the foreign export estimates for the default commercial fishing sector (Sector 16), re-estimated foreign exports for raw seafood from new data (see below) and assumed that foreign exports of raw seafood occur at the wholesale level and not the harvesting level.  Additionally, foreign exports for the 23 new processing sectors added to the model were estimated by constructing 23 separate sub-regional IMPLAN Pro models to obtain the default inventory seafood processing export values in each sub-region.

Foreign exports of seafood produced at the wholesale-level in the Northeast Region were calculated according to the following six steps.

Step 1 -- Northeast dealer reports were used to calculate the value of landings by species for the top three to five species landed (by value) for each harvesting sector gear type in the model.

Step 2 --  The proportion of total value by species and product type that is exported out of the US was calculated.  New England and Mid-Atlantic foreign trade data by species and product type is available from the Fisheries Statistics & Economics Division of the National Marine Fisheries Service (NMFS) at http://www.st.nmfs.gov/st1/trade/index.html.  These data are purchased from the Foreign Trade Division of the U.S. Census Bureau and provide information on trade ($s and lbs) through specific U.S. customs districts such as the New England and the Mid-Atlantic regions.   We divided the value exported by species and product type by the region-wide export value of total landings (average export price multiplied by total landings) to obtain the proportion of total sales exported out of the U.S. by product type.

Step 3 --  Fresh fillets and fresh and frozen whole fish were assumed to be exported by wholesalers. The remaining product type categories (frozen fillets, salted, dried, minced frozen, smoked, and an other product type category) were assumed to be exported by seafood processors.  We summed the export proportions from Step 2 across the three wholesale product type categories to estimate total Northeast Region export proportions (in terms of value) by species.

Step 4 -- Weighted average wholesaler export proportions were calculated from the harvesting gear types.  The export proportions from Step 3 were weighted by the proportions of landed value by species (for the top three to five valued species) to total landed value for each of the harvesting gear types.  These species-level proportions for each gear type were then summed across species to obtain the proportions of wholesaler output that will be exported out of the U.S., originating from the 18 different gear types in the model.  Note that the export rates derived from each gear type are assumed to be the same across the 23 sub-regions. 

Step 5 -- The wholesale export rates from Step 4 were then multiplied by the output values contained in the dealer transaction matrix (adjusted upward assuming a margin of 40%) to obtain the wholesale dealer export values across the 23 wholesale sectors associated with each harvesting sector in the model.

Step 6 -- We then summed the wholesale export values from Step 5 across harvesting sectors for each of the 23 wholesalers and divided this value by the total sales from each wholesale sector.  The resulting values show the average proportion of total seafood sales that is exported out of the U.S. by each wholesaler.  The average amount exported by seafood dealers ranges from a low of 18% in the VA North sub-region to 70% in the Southern ME sub-region.  These proportions were then multiplied by the margined wholesale output values contained in the SAOutput table (the wholesale sectors are treated as margin sectors in the model) to determine the value of foreign exports for each of the 23 wholesale sectors in the model.

SAOutput

The SAOutput table is a vector of output values in millions of dollars that represents an industries total production.  There is a single value for each of the 997 sectors in the model.  We removed the default commercial fishing sector’s output value and the default seafood processing sector’s output value, and then added the appropriate production values for the 490 new sectors in the Northeast Region model.

SAValue Added

This table details payments made/received by each industry to employee compensation (wage and salary payments, insurance, retirement, etc.), proprietary income (all income received), other property type income (payments from interest, rents, royalties, dividends, corporate profits, etc.) and indirect business taxes (primarily excise and sales taxes).  The value added transactions associated with the default commercial fishing and seafood processing sectors were removed and the appropriate values for the 490 new sectors were added to the table. 

Observed RPCs

The Observed RPCs table contains forced regional purchase coefficient values for all states in the model.  We removed the values associated with the default commercial fishing and seafood processing sectors and added the appropriate RPC values by state FIPS codes for the 490 new sectors added to the model.  We used the average RPC option in IMPLAN Pro so the same RPC value was applied across states for each of the 490 new sectors.  However, because of the way the model calculates impacts across sectors, virtually all of the RPC values for the new sectors were set to zero: the RPCs for the bait sectors were set to one.  The model-generated default RPC values were used for the other 507 sectors in the model.

RPC Methods

This table contains information for creation of the regional purchase coefficients.  Similar to the modifications made for to many of the other tables, we removed the information associated with the default commercial fishing and seafood processing sectors and then added the relevant information for the 490 new sectors to the table. 

Deflator1

The Deflator1 table contains deflators that account for relative price changes during different time periods.  The IMPLAN Pro deflators are derived from the Bureau of Labor Statistics Growth Model.  The 2001 IMPLAN Pro data base contains deflators from 1977 to 2010 for each commodity in the model.  We eliminated the default commercial fishing sector deflators and applied these same values to the 394 new harvesting sectors in the table.  We also removed the default seafood processing sector and applied those deflators to the 23 new sub-regional seafood processing sectors that we added to the table.

rptSAFinal Demands

This is a report table that is used by the IMPLAN Pro software to view final demand purchases of industry outputs. Report tables are not used by the IMPLAN Pro software for model construction or impact analysis; they simply provide a means to view data from within the IMPLAN Pro system.  Therefore, modifications to this table are not absolutely necessary, but are required in order to use the IMPLAN Pro reporting feature.

To keep the software fully functional we modified the final demand values in this table.  We removed the final demand values associated with both the default commercial fishing and seafood processing sectors, and added the appropriate data from the SAFinal Demands and SAForeign Exports table.  Note that modifications in ACCESS are not acknowledged by the IMPLAN Pro software so the social accounts must be regenerated after changes are made in order for the reporting features in IMPLAN Pro to work properly.

rptSAIndustry Data

This is another report table that is used by the IMPLAN Pro software to show industry output, employment, and value added information by sector.  Changes to this table will not effect model construction or impact analysis, but need to be made in order to use the reporting feature in the IMPLAN Pro software.  We eliminated the industry data associated with the default commercial fishing and processing sectors, and added the appropriate data from the SAOutput table, SAEmployment table, and the SAValue Added table.


6.   IMPACT ESTIMATION

The NERIOM provides analysts with a tool for assessing how the impact of fishery management decisions may be distributed across different sectors of regional and sub-regional economies.  However, any impact assessment must begin with an externally derived estimate of how any such action would affect commercial fishing sales.  The economy-wide backward-linked impacts of proposed fishery management actions are estimated by applying these exogenously determined gross output changes to the appropriate NERIOM multipliers.  As discussed in Section 2, an IMPLAN Pro model can accept exogenous gross output (i.e., sales) changes as entries if the RPCs of the directly impacted sectors are set to zero.  In addition to deriving exogenous gross output changes for the harvesting sectors, however, the NERIOM also requires exogenous estimates of how the sales will change for wholesale seafood dealers, fish exchange/auctions, and seafood processors.  Thus, the RPCs for all of the fishing-related sectors in the NERIOM were set to zero.  By simultaneously multiplying the estimated exogenous gross output changes for the harvesting sectors, wholesale seafood dealer sectors, fish exchange/auction sectors, and seafood processing sectors by their corresponding model-generated multipliers, the backward-linked effects associated with changes in commercial fishing sales and the additional backward-linked multiplier effects that may occur through changes in local supply to wholesalers, auction houses, and seafood processors can be measured.  This modeling approach, however, requires not only an external estimate of how management actions will impact harvesting revenues, but also how the actions will impact the revenues of auction houses, wholesalers, and seafood processors.

In previous applications of this approach, we began with a mathematical programming model to estimate how ex-vessel revenues for each of the commercial harvesting gear sectors in the NERIOM might change upon implementation of the proposed regulations.  Mathematical programming models are but one method that may be used to estimate potential changes in harvesting revenues.  Other methods may be appropriate depending upon the management changes that may be under consideration.

Once the exogenous ex-vessel revenue changes are determined, adjustments can be made to account for the additional revenue changes that may occur to the auction houses, seafood wholesalers, and seafood processors.  To estimate these changes, we first constructed a dealer transaction matrix from 2001 Northeast dealer weigh-out data.  Northeast weigh-out slips record all transactions between federally permitted harvesters and wholesale dealers.  Thus, it was possible to create a transaction matrix that showed the value of seafood sold by each of the 394 commercial fishing gear sectors in the NERIOM to each of the 23 wholesale dealers and 4 fish exchange/auction houses in the model.  Fish/exchange auction houses are also required to hold a federal dealer permit.  The transaction matrix could then be used to determine how changes in a particular harvesting sector’s ex-vessel revenues would affect the value of purchases associated with the 23 wholesale dealers and the 4 fish exchange/auction houses.  Wholesale seafood dealer gross revenue changes were then calculated by assuming the mark-up on these purchases was 40% - the average Fulton Market margin in 2001.  The values of the mark-ups were then entered as the change in direct sales for each wholesale dealer sector in the NERIOM since these sectors are treated as margin sectors by the model.  The 4 fish exchange/auction houses are also treated as margin sectors in the model.  The values of these mark-ups were calculated by dividing the average exchange fee per pound (11 cents) by the average price per pound of seafood sold at each exchange.  The estimated gross revenue changes associated with the 4 fish exchange/auction houses were then multiplied by the mark-up values (approximately 9.7%) and entered as the change in direct sales for each fish exchange/auction house.  Gross revenue changes for seafood processors are estimated following the steps described below.

Step 1 -- Calculate the estimated value of seafood exported by wholesale seafood dealers.   Multiply the estimated gross revenue changes for each wholesaler by the average proportion of total seafood sales that is exported out of the U.S. by each wholesaler (derivation of these proportions were explained in Section 5). 

Step 2 -- Calculate the value of seafood left in the Northeast that is available to be purchased by Northeast seafood processors.  This step simply requires removing the estimated value of seafood exported by wholesale dealers.  Thus, these values are obtained by subtracting the export estimates calculated in Step 1 for each wholesale dealer from the estimated wholesaler’s gross revenue change.

Step 3 -- Calculate the estimated value of wholesale seafood that will actually be purchased by seafood processors in the Northeast.  As noted earlier IMPLAN Pro data for the Northeast shows seafood processors purchasing approximately 48% of the sales produced by the commercial fishing sector in the Northeast in 2001.  This value can be determined by constructing a default Northeast IMPLAN Pro model and then viewing the commodity balance sheet for the commercial fishing sector.  As we have said, most of the seafood purchased by seafood processors generally flows through wholesalers before reaching the processing level and all federally permitted commercial harvesters are required to sell to establishments that hold federal dealer permits.  Thus, in the NERIOM it is assumed that seafood processors will purchase product from wholesalers and not directly from commercial harvesters.  As such, 48% of Northeast wholesale dealer sales – and not commercial harvester sales - are assumed to be purchased by seafood processors in the region.  The value of the purchases are then calculated by multiplying the result of Step 2 by 0.48 for each wholesale dealer in the model.  The other 52% of wholesale seafood sales are purchased by industries such as eating and drinking establishments, hospitals, hotels, etc. and by final demand sectors other than exports (i.e., households and government entities; see Figure 2).  These purchases are assumed to remain constant in the NERIOM, however.

Step 4 -- Determine the value of purchases by seafood processors that will be derived from each wholesaler.  In Step 3, the value of wholesale seafood dealer output that is purchased by seafood processors was calculated.  In this step, we have to allocate the purchases to specific seafood processors.  In states with more than one sub-region, seafood processors are assumed to purchase from all in-state wholesale dealers according to seafood processor output proportions contained in the NERIOM.

Step 5 -- Convert the impacts on purchases to gross revenue changes.  To calculate estimated gross revenue changes, margins are applied to the values estimated in Step 4.  The margins were derived from each sub-regional seafood processing sector’s production function and represent the value of output less the cost of the seafood purchased.  The margins varied from 62% to 67% across sub-regions, and since seafood processors are considered producing sectors in the NERIOM, the estimates calculated in Step 4 were marked-up according to the appropriate sub-regional margin values.  These producer values are then entered as the change in direct sales for each seafood processing sector.

The estimated direct changes in gross revenues for harvesters, fish exchanges/auctions, wholesale seafood dealers, and seafood processors are then compiled into an impact vector and entered into a Microsoft Excel template that can be imported into IMPLAN Pro (see Appendix I in Olson and Lindall, 1999 for details about the template).  The impact vector can then be applied to the multipliers in the NERIOM to arrive at the economy-wide impacts of the proposed regulation in the Northeast.6

Allocation of Indirect and Induced Impacts to Sub-regions

The NERIOM explicitly addresses sub-regional impacts for the seafood producing sectors that are estimated to be directly affected: the commercial harvesting gear sectors, the fish exchange/auction sectors, the wholesale seafood dealer sectors, and the seafood processing sectors.  The sum of the sub-regional impact estimates for these sectors in the NERIOM equals the regional impact.  The NERIOM, however, calculates only Northeast region-level impacts for the sectors that are estimated to be indirectly affected, therefore a method had to be developed that could apportion the estimated region-wide effects on indirectly affected sectors to the sub-regions contained in the NERIOM.

The allocation method we developed is based on the relative importance of each sub-region’s economy (determined to be directly affected) to the total Northeast region’s economy.  We assumed that the indirect impacts would be distributed according to output, personal income, and employment shares in each of the sub-regions that were directly impacted.  The shares were first determined by constructing separate default IMPLAN Pro models for each of the 24 sub-regions. Then the default output, personal income, and employment estimates contained in each sub-regional model were divided by the regional totals.  Using output estimates as an example, if Tir is equal to the total default output for each industry sector (i) in each sub-region (r), then the shares can be represented as .   These shares are then adjusted three times before they are applied to the IMPLAN-generated region-wide estimates of indirect impacts. 

The first adjusted share calculation maintains the unadjusted shares (Sirs) for industries located in the directly impacted sub-regions and the non-maritime sub-region and sets the remaining shares to zero.  If Dr indicates the sub-regions that are directly impacted (i.e., revenue changes will occur for commercial harvesters, seafood dealers, fish exchange/auction houses, or seafood processors in that sub-region) and equals the first adjusted share then for all Dr > 0 then = Sir.  If Dr= 0 then = 0.  Additionally, if the subscript r  equals the non-maritime sub-region then let r = NM and == SiNM .

The shares are then adjusted a second time to capture the relative importance of industry output in each of the directly affected sub-regions to total industry output across all of the directly affected sub-regions.  If Bir is set equal to and equals the second adjusted share then   for , otherwise if then = 0. Finally, the non-maritime Northeast region shares for each industry i are then subdivided into non-maritime New England shares and non-maritime Mid-Atlantic shares.  The adjusted shares are calculated based on the proportion of direct impacts that occur in each of the two aggregate sub-regions to the total direct impacts in the Northeast region.  Mathematically, if equals the third adjusted share and the subscripts NE and MA represent New England and Mid-Atlantic sub-regions, respectively, then for r = NM,  and .  For all , .

The region-wide IMPLAN-generated impact estimates for each of the indirectly affected sectors can then be apportioned across the directly impacted sub-regions by multiplying the estimates by the third adjusted shares.  The shares sum to one which ensures that the sum of the resulting sub-regional impacts will equal the model-generated region-wide impacts. 

Hypothetical Impact Assessment

Hypothetical reductions in medium bottom trawl ex-vessel revenues are used to illustrate the outputs produced by the NERIOM.  If it is assumed that a reduction in landings is required to meet an annual rebuilding target, and the reduction in landings is predicted to cause a $500,000 decline in total ex-vessel revenues for medium bottom trawl vessels in each of the coastal sub-regions from Maine through New York, the NERIOM can be employed to assess the multiplier effects (sales, personal income, and employment) associated with the estimated decline in revenues.  Tables 10 through 15 show the results of this hypothetical impact assessment.  

The total exogenously determined direct loss in ex-vessel revenues for medium bottom trawl vessels across all the sub-regions in the Northeast sums to $5.5 million ($5.0 million across the sub-regions in New England and $500 thousand in the Mid-Atlantic sub-regions; Table 10 and Table 11, respectively).7  Exogenously determined losses in wholesale dealer sales of seafood are estimated to approach $1.16 million in New England and $230 thousand in the Mid-Atlantic.  Additionally, exogenously determined losses in sales by fish exchange/auction houses in New England are estimated to be $196 thousand.  Finally, exogenously estimated losses in seafood processing revenues are estimated to be $5.56 million in New England and $430 thousand in the Mid-Atlantic.  As previously mentioned, wholesale dealers and fish exchange/auction houses are treated as margin sectors so their sales estimates in the NERIOM reflect only the value added to the seafood being sold (i.e., total gross sales less the cost of the purchased seafood  ).  The NERIOM then uses all of the exogenously determined estimates of revenue changes to the commercial harvesters, wholesale dealers, fish exchange/auction houses, and seafood processors to calculate the indirect and induced multiplier effects of those changes.  At the greatest level of detail, indirect and induced effects can be estimated for up to 507 sectors in each of the 24 sub-regions.  Thus, for presentation purposes, the results have been aggregated into 15 summary categories for each sub-region.  Of the total sales impact in New England, 68% is associated with direct gross revenue losses to medium bottom trawlers, seafood dealers, fish exchange/auction houses, and seafood processors.  The remaining 32% of the losses in New England are the indirect and induced effects that occur among industries that provide goods and services in the production of seafood.  The largest indirect revenue losses in New England are estimated for establishments classified as service industries ($1.83 million).  Across the Mid-Atlantic, however, the indirect and induced effects comprise nearly 84% of the total sales impact.  This seeming disproportionate effect is mainly a function of the substantial industry-level infrastructure that exists in the Mid-Atlantic sub-regions.  Mid-Atlantic based businesses produce a greater percentage of the goods and services that are used in the production of seafood in the Northeast region.  The largest indirect and induced revenue losses in the Mid-Atlantic are predicted to occur in service industries ($1.83 million), finance, insurance, and real estate ($947.36 thousand), and wholesale trade ($812.35 thousand). 

Important differences in impacts across the 23 sub-regions are also predicted to occur.  Revenue losses are estimated to range from a high of $4.35 million in the New York Seacoast sub-region to no estimated losses in the 9 sub-regions south of New Jersey (excluding the non-maritime Mid-Atlantic sub-region).  The comparatively large losses shown for the New York Seacoast sub-region can generally be traced to a greater reliance on goods and services produced from within the New York Seacoast sub-region than from any of the other sub-regions in the NERIOM.  In the 9 sub-regions south of New Jersey, there are no predicted direct revenue losses for any of the seafood producing sectors (i.e., medium bottom trawlers, seafood dealers, fish exchange/auctions, or seafood processors).  It is assumed, therefore, that there will also be no indirect or induced effects in these sub-regions.  In the Downeast Maine sub-region and in the New Jersey North and New Jersey South sub-regions there are no predicted direct revenue losses associated with medium bottom trawlers, but there are direct losses associated with one or more of the other seafood producing sectors.  Indirect and induced effects are, therefore, predicted to occur as supporting businesses supply fewer goods and services to seafood dealers, fish exchanges/auctions, and seafood processors.  It is also worth noting that supporting businesses in the non-maritime sub-regions in New England and the Mid-Atlantic are predicted to incur substantial revenue losses even though there are no direct revenue losses associated with any of the seafood producing sectors in these sub-regions.  These losses result because as the revenues of businesses located in the coastal sub-regions decline, they, in turn, purchase smaller quantities of goods and services from non-maritime businesses (i.e., indirect effects).  In addition, as employee earnings decline, household spending falls, initiating further rounds of revenue repercussions in the non-maritime sub-regions (i.e., induced effects).

Although losses in sales represent a loss in output, losses in personal income and jobs are a more telling indicator of economic impact.  The total loss in personal income is estimated to range up to $1.67 million in the New York Seacoast sub-region (Table 12 and Table 13).  In terms of jobs, the are no estimated impacts in the 9 sub-regions south of New Jersey while the New York Seacoast sub-region is predicted to incur the largest job impact (35; Table 14 and Table 15).  As was the case for changes in sales, a much larger proportion of the total income and employment impacts fall on the seafood producing sectors in New England than in the Mid-Atlantic.  Nearly 70% of the total income impact and total employment impact in New England can be traced to medium bottom trawlers, seafood dealers, fish exchange/auctions, and seafood processors.  In the Mid-Atlantic, however, only 18% of the total estimated income changes and 23% of the total employment changes can be traced to the seafood producing businesses.  As previously indicated, the disparity is generally due to the substantial industry-level infrastructure that supplies seafood establishments in the Mid-Atlantic region.


7.  DISCUSSION

The NERIOM has been designed to calculate the backward linked multiplier effects induced by exogenous changes in gross revenues for commercial harvesters, fish exchange/auction houses, seafood dealers, and seafood processors.  Assessments such as this are essential to fishery management agencies that want to know how management actions will impact regional economies. 

One of the more useful features of the modeling approach presented here is that it is based on traditional Leontief input-output relationships, so it can be incorporated into ready-made input-output systems such as IMPLAN Pro.  Ready-made models reduce the cost and complexity of model formulation and the time required to generate impact estimates.  This is important, because the primary reason for building the NERIOM is for use in relative policy appraisals of alternative fishery management actions.  The ability to be able to predict the multiplier effects of policy-induced changes in a timely manner, will allow regional decision makers in the Northeast to compare and contrast the outcomes of alternative management strategies prior to choosing the final measures.

Ready-made regional input-output models also offer considerable industry detail to trace backward linkages and to generate disaggregated estimates of indirect and induced multiplier effects.  In contrast, the multiplier effects generated from other types of input-output models (e.g., mixed exogenous/endogenous variables models and spreadsheet-type models based on limited input-output multipliers) are usually derived from aggregated or condensed versions of these same ready-made models.  As a consequence, the models lack the sectoral detail contained in the NERIOM and generally do not provide the multiplier effects necessary for fully informed decision making.

The multiplier effects generated by the NERIOM, however, are static and should be viewed as the immediate/short-term impacts of the change being analyzed.  There are several technological assumptions built into the model, such as fixity of prices and zero-substitution elasticities in consumption and production that make it difficult to assess how the seafood producing sectors will adjust over time.  For example, vessels may be able to offset initial ex-vessel revenue losses due to a cutback in a landings quota by switching to other fisheries.  In addition, direct revenue losses to seafood dealers, auction houses, and seafood processors may also decline over time as seafood flows from other fisheries increase.  The reduction in local supply may also cause prices and/or imports to increase lowering the estimated direct revenue losses even further.  Unfortunately, these types of longer run adjustments are generally not captured in input-output models.  As harvesters, seafood dealers, and seafood processors adapt to policy-induced reductions in supply over time, it is likely that at least some of the losses estimated with the NERIOM will be avoided through shifts to other fisheries, price increases, and additional imports.

The impacts estimated by the NERIOM also exclude the retail level.  Although it is possible that restaurants and food service establishments in the Northeast could experience a reduction in local supply because of a restrictive fishery management action, we have assumed that consumers would simply choose from among the many other close substitutes (e.g., other fish species, chicken, turkey, etc.) such that retail level gross revenues would remain unchanged. 

At present, the NERIOM can accept input data for the years 2001 through 2010.  Although the data contained in IMPLAN Pro are based on economic relationships in 2001, the impacts of management actions in succeeding years are determined by converting the estimated changes in gross revenues to year 2001 dollars before the impacts are estimated.  The NERIOM then automatically converts the impact estimates back to the year of the input data (through 2010).   This process accounts for the effects of inflation on the impact estimates.  However, the economic relationships that existed in 2001 are only approximations of the ones that may exist in subsequent years.  Technological change and price variability may alter an industry’s production process over time, and hence the businesses that are impacted by changes in fishery management actions.  Technology and prices tend to change rather slowly, however, so the mismatch between the economic relationships in 2001 and near subsequent years is likely to be minimal.  Nonetheless, since the NERIOM assumes these economic relationships remain constant, an element of uncertainty is introduced into the model’s estimates.

Product flow assumptions are another source of possible uncertainty.  The federal Northeast dealer data base tracks the flow of seafood from harvesters to seafood dealers and most fish exchange/auction houses (e.g., the flow of seafood to Fulton Market in New York is unknown), but documentation of successive levels of sales among seafood industry establishments in the Northeast region are not available.  In particular, virtually no data is available to measure transactions between and among fish exchange/auction houses, seafood dealers, and seafood processors.  Thus, the NERIOM assumes a linear flow of product sales from harvesters to fish exchange/auction houses and wholesale seafood dealers, and then finally onto seafood processors.  To the extent that these simplifying assumptions underestimate the number of transactions between the seafood producing establishments in the Northeast region, the value added by each successive level of sale will be underestimated.  If this is the case, the impacts generated by the NERIOM are also underestimated.

The allocation method used to translate region-wide indirect impacts into sub-regional impacts ensures that that the sum of the sub-regional impacts will equal the model-generated region-wide impacts, but the method is based on weighted ratios that may only approximate true economic relationships in the Northeast region.  For example, the total Northeast region ice manufacturing sales impact in the hypothetical impact assessment shown above was $40.69 thousand (Table 10 and Table 11).  This model-generated indirect impact was then distributed across sub-regions that were predicted to be directly impacted based on the relative importance of ice manufacturing across each of the directly impacted subregions and the non-maritime sub-regions.  Since ice manufacturing output (i.e., sales) in the Boston Massachusetts sub-region comprises 6.48% of the regional total, 6.48% ($6,283) of model-generated regional total is allocated to the Boston Massachusetts sub-region.  While the proportional allocation method is computationally efficient and concise, it only distributes the model-generated region-wide indirect and induced impacts to sub-regions where direct impacts are predicted to occur.  If businesses located in sub-regions that are not predicted to be directly impacted are affected the weighting method may misrepresent the distribution of impacts. 

Consideration was given to allocating indirect and induced impacts across all 24 sub-regions according to the default fixed output, income, and employment shares in each sub-region.  This method would result in estimates of indirect and induced impacts in all 24 sub-regions, but it is insensitive to the location of the direct impacts.  The allocation method we followed places more weight on indirectly affected businesses located in the sub-regions where the direct effects take place.  Construction of a full multi-regional model that explicitly measures the linkages between indirectly affected sectors in each of the sub-regions would likely provide more accurate sub-regional estimates of indirect impacts.  However, a model of this kind in the Northeast region is computationally unworkable since it would require over 12 thousand sectors to measure the economic relationships that exist between the indirectly affected sectors in each of the 24 sub-regions (i.e., 507 possible indirectly affected sectors * 24 sub-regions = 12,168 sectors).


ENDNOTES

1.  This is known as closing the model with respect to households.  In a closed input-output model, the household sector is moved from the final-demand column and placed inside the A matrix, making it one of the endogenous sectors.

2.  Employment and personal income multipliers can also be derived from input-output models by multiplying the model-generated output changes by an industry’s employment to output ratio, and an industry’s personal income (employee compensation plus proprietor’s income) to output ratio, respectively.

3.  An RPC measures the portion of the total regional demand for a particular industry sector’s output that is supplied by local producers.

4.  For a derivation of the equivalence between the total aggregate impact estimates generated from a mixed exogenous/endogenous variables model and the approach described in Tanjuakio, Hastings, and Tytus (1996) see Steinback 2004.

5.  The addition of fish exchanges/auctions could not be extended to the New York sub-region where the largest wholesale market in the Northeast operates – the Fulton Market, because specific data on the flow of seafood through this market, though formerly available is not now so.

6.  Although the effects on the economy of direct changes in gross revenues for harvesters, fish exchanges/auctions, wholesale seafood dealers, and seafood processors are estimated simultaneously in the NERIOM, the model avoids double counting because the RPC’s for these sectors have been set to zero.  Setting the RPCs of the outputs produced by the directly impacted sectors to zero prior to constructing the direct input coefficient matrix (A matrix) effectively prevents other local industries from buying these outputs and, thus, removes the possibility of double counting impacts.  In other words, the impacts associated with changes in seafood dealer revenues and fish exchange revenues exclude the impacts associated with changes in commercial harvesting revenues, and revenue changes associated with seafood processors exclude those changes attributable to seafood dealers, fish exchanges, and commercial harvesters.  Thus, the impacts associated with revenue changes to these sectors can be summed to obtain the total effect on sales, income, and employment without double counting impacts.

7.  In 2001, there were no reported landings for medium bottom trawl vessels in the Downeast Maine sub-region.  Thus, there are no losses in ex-vessel revenues reported for the medium bottom trawl sector in this sub-region in Table 10.

back to top

REFERENCES CITED

Anonymous, 1995. "SIMLOB - The resource and harvest sector components of the North American Lobster (Homarus americanus) market model: final report," Department of Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, University of Rhode Island, Kingston, RI.

Georgianna, D.; Cass A.; Brough K. 1998. “The cost of hook fishing for groundfish in Northeastern United States,” University of Massachusetts Dartmouth, National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration Cooperative Marine Education and Research Award, Contract Number NA67FEO420.

Georgianna, D.; Cass A.; Amaral, P. 1999. “The cost of fishing for sea scallops in Northeastern United States,” University of Massachusetts Dartmouth, National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration Cooperative Marine Education and Research Award, National Marine Fisheries Service, Contract Number NA67FEO420.

Johnson, T.G.; Kulshreshtha, S.N. 1982.  Exogenizing agriculture in an input-output model to estimate relative impacts of different farm types. Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 7(2):187-198.

Kirkley, J.E.; Ryan, W.; Duberg, J. 2004. “Assessing the economic importance of commercial fisheries in the Mid-Atlantic region: A user’s guide to the Mid-Atlantic input/output model,” Virginia Institute of Marine Science, National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration Cooperative Marine Education and Research Award.

Lallemand, P.; Gates, J.M.; Dirlam, J.; Cho, J. 1999. “The costs of large trawlers in the Northeast,” Department of Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, The University of Rhode Island.

Lallemand, P.; Gates, J.M.; Dirlam, J.; Cho, J. 1998. “The costs of small trawlers in the Northeast,” Department of Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, The University of Rhode Island.

Leung, P.; Pooley, S. 2002.  Regional economic impacts of reductions in fisheries production: a supply-driven approach. Marine Resource Economics 16(4), 251-262.

Miller, R.E.; Blair, P.D. 1985. Input-output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions. Prentice-Hall, London.

Minnesota IMPLAN Group, Inc., IMPLAN System (data and software), 1725 Tower Drive West, Suite 140, Stillwater, MN 55082 www.implan.com.

Olson, D.; Lindall, S. 1999. IMPLAN Professional Software, Analysis, and Data Guide. Minnesota IMPLAN Group, Inc., 1725 Tower Drive West, Suite 140, Stillwater, MN 55082, www.implan.com.

Steinback, S.R. 2004. Using ready-made regional input-output models to estimate backward-linkage effects of exogenous output shocks. The Review of Regional Studies 34(1):57-71.

Tanjuakio, R.V.; Hastings, S.E.; Tytus, P.J. 1996.  The economic contribution of agriculture in Delaware.  Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 25(1):46-53.

TechLaw, Inc. 2001. “The Economic Contribution of the Sport Fishing, Commercial Fishing, and Seafood Industries to New York State,” Prepared for New York SeaGrant.

U.S. Census Bureau, 2004. “Groceries and Related Products: 2002,” 2002 Economic Census, Wholesale Trade, Industry Series.

U.S. Census Bureau, 2003. 2001. County Business Patterns (NAICS) Summary Tables, http://censtats.census.gov/cbpnaic/cbpnaic.shtml, generated (7 October 2004).

Acronyms
CGEM = Computable General Equilibrium Model
NAICS = North American Industry Classification System
NEPA = National Environmental Policy Act
NERIOM = Northeast Region Input-Output Model
NMFS

= National Marine Fisheries Service

SIA = Social Impact Assessment
URI = University of Rhode Island
VTR = NMFS’ Vessel Trip Reports
www.nefsc.noaa.gov
NMFS Search
Link Disclaimer
webMASTER
Privacy Policy
(File Modified Dec. 03 2012)