Parliamentary system

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Jump to: navigation, search
Map of different governmental systems
  Constitutional monarchies in which authority is vested in a parliament.
  Parliamentary republics where parliaments are effectively supreme over a separate head of state.
  Parliamentary republics with an executive president elected by and responsible to a parliament.

A parliamentary system is a system of democratic government in which the executive branch (the government) derives its legitimacy from and are accountable to the legislature (the parliament); the executive and legislative branches are thus interconnected. In a parliamentary system, the head of state is normally a different person from the head of government. This is in contrast to a presidential system, where the head of state also serves as head of government and where the executive branch doesn't derive its legitimacy from the legislature.

Countries with parliamentary systems may be constitutional monarchies, where a monarch is the ceremonial head of state while a prime minister is the head of government (such as United Kingdom, Sweden and Japan), or parliamentary republics, where a president is the ceremonial head of state while a prime minister is the head of government (such as Ireland, Germany , India and Italy). In a few parliamentary republics, such as South Africa and Botswana, the head of government is also head of state, but is elected by and is answerable to the parliament.

Contents

[edit] History

The modern concept of prime ministerial government originated with the Kingdom of Great Britain (1707–1800) and its contemporary, the Parliamentary System in Sweden (1721–1772).

Prince Elector George Ludwig of Hanover, Germany acceded to the throne of Great Britain after his cousin Queen Anne died with no heirs. As King George I he chaired the cabinet and chose ministers of the government; however, he initially spoke no English. This shifted the balance of power towards the leading minister, or first minister, who de facto chaired the cabinet. During his reign a gradual democratization of parliament with the broadening of the voting franchise[citation needed] increased the parliament's role in controlling government, and in deciding who the king could ask to form a government. Towards the end of his reign, actual power was held by Sir Robert Walpole, Britain's first prime minister. Later the Great Reform Act of 1832 broadened the franchise and was accompanied by increasing parliamentary dominance, with parliament always deciding who was prime minister.

[edit] Background

A parliamentary system may be a bicameral system with two chambers of parliament (or houses): an elected lower house, and an upper house or Senate which may be appointed or elected by a different mechanism from the lower house. Another possibility is a unicameral system with just one parliamentary chamber. Scholars of democracy such as Arend Lijphart distinguish two types of parliamentary democracies: the Westminster and Consensus systems.[1]

Implementations of the parliamentary system can also differ on whether the formation of government needs the explicit approval of the parliament, rather than just the absence of its disapproval, and under what conditions (if any) the government has the right to dissolve the parliament, like Jamaica and many others.[citation needed]

Parliamentarianism may also apply to local governments. An example is the city of Oslo, which has an executive council (Byråd) as a part of the parliamentary system.

The Parliamentary system can be contrasted with a presidential system which operates under a stricter separation of powers, whereby the executive does not form part of, nor is appointed by, the parliamentary or legislative body. In such a system, congresses do not select or dismiss heads of governments, and governments cannot request an early dissolution as may be the case for parliaments. There also exists the semi-presidential system that draws on both presidential systems and parliamentary systems by combining a powerful president with an executive responsible to parliament, as for example the French Fifth Republic.

[edit] Advantages of parliamentary systems

One of the commonly attributed advantages to parliamentary systems is that it is faster and easier to pass legislation,[2] as the executive branch is dependent on the direct or indirect support of the legislative branch and often includes members of the legislature. Thus the executive (as the majority party or coalition of parties in the legislature) has a majority of the votes, enabling them to pass legislation. In a presidential system, the executive is often chosen independently from the legislature. If the executive and the majority of the legislature are from different political parties, then stalemate can occur. Thus the executive might not be able to implement their legislative proposals. An executive in any system (be it parliamentary, presidential or semi-presidential) is chiefly voted into office on the basis of his or her party's platform/manifesto, and the same is also true of the legislative branch.

In addition to quicker legislative action, Parliamentarianism has attractive features for nations that are ethnically, racially, or ideologically divided. In a presidential system, all executive power is vested in one person: the president. In a parliamentary system, with a collegial executive, power is more divided. In the 1989 Lebanese Taif Agreement, in order to give Muslims greater political power, Lebanon moved from a semi-presidential system with a strong president to a system more structurally similar to classical parliamentarianism. Iraq similarly disdained a presidential system out of fears that such a system would be tantamount to Shiite domination; Afghanistan's minorities refused to go along with a presidency as strong as the Pashtuns desired.[citation needed]

It can also be argued that power is more evenly spread out in the power structure of parliamentarianism. The prime minister is seldom as important as a ruling president, and there tends to be a higher focus on voting for a party and its political ideas than voting for an actual person.

In The English Constitution, Walter Bagehot praised parliamentarianism for producing serious debates, for allowing change in power without an election, and for allowing elections at any time. Bagehot considered the four-year election rule of the United States to be unnatural.[citation needed]

Some scholars like Juan Linz, Fred Riggs, Bruce Ackerman, and Robert Dahl claim that parliamentarianism is less prone to authoritarian collapse. These scholars point out that since World War II, two-thirds of Third World countries establishing parliamentary governments successfully made the transition to democracy. By contrast, no Third World presidential system successfully made the transition to democracy without experiencing coups and other constitutional breakdowns.[citation needed]

A recent World Bank study found that parliamentary systems are associated with less corruption.[3]

Some constituencies may have a popular local candidate under an unpopular leader (or the reverse), forcing a difficult choice on the electorate. Mixed member proportional representation (where voters cast two ballots) can make this choice easier by allowing voters to cast one vote for the local candidate but also cast a second vote for another party.

Although Walter Bagehot praised parliamentarianism for allowing an election to take place at any time, the lack of a definite election calendar can be abused. Previously under some systems, such as the British, a ruling party could schedule elections when it felt that it was likely to retain power, and so avoid elections at times of unpopularity – . Election timing in the UK, however, is now partly fixed under the Fixed-term Parliaments Act 2011. Thus, by wise timing of elections, in a parliamentary system a party can extend its rule for longer than is feasible in a functioning presidential system. This problem can be alleviated somewhat by setting fixed dates for parliamentary elections, as is the case in several of Australia's state parliaments. In other systems, such as the Dutch and the Belgian, the ruling party or coalition has some flexibility in determining the election date. Conversely, flexibility in the timing of parliamentary elections can avoid periods of legislative gridlock that can occur in a fixed period presidential system.

Critics of the Westminster parliamentary system point out that people with significant popular support in the community are prevented from becoming prime minister if they cannot get elected to parliament since there is no option to "run for prime minister" as one can run for president under a presidential system. Additionally, prime ministers may lose their positions if they lose their seats in parliament, even though they may still be popular nationally. Supporters of parliamentarianism respond by saying that as members of parliament, prime ministers are elected first to represent their electoral constituents and if they lose their support then consequently they are no longer entitled to be prime minister.[citation needed] This is, however, a moot point if proportional representation is used.

Voting Choice Theory in Parliamentary Systems

Voters can choose among many parties in parliamentary systems, whereas the US Congressional system virtually ensures only two parties. Because Parliamentary systems allocate additional seats based upon the total nationwide voting percentage a party wins, in addition to the seats won in each voting district, voters know their votes for a less popular party candidate will still count for something even if their candidate does not win that district.

In contrast, the U.S. voter knows such a vote is essentially wasted, because there is nothing gained when the system is winner take all. Indeed, U.S. voters know that voting for a candidate from any party other than the two most popular ones will actually help the candidate they least desire among the top two parties. This happens because if voters choose a candidate from other than the two major parties, they are peeling off votes from the major party candidate who most closely aligns with the views of their minor party candidate, thus helping the other major party candidate, who least reflects these voters desires, to win the election. With no consolation prize in the form of the extra Parliamentary seats allocated to parties based on their nationwide proportion of the total vote, it is irrational for voters to choose from any but the two most popular party candidates.

[edit] Countries with a parliamentary system of government

Sansad Bhavan, parliament building of largest democracy, India.
The New South Wales Parliament is Australia's oldest parliament. First elections were held in 1843.
Knesset of Israel in Jerusalem.
The administrative building of the Albanian Parliament

[edit] Unicameral system

This table shows countries with parliament consisting of a single house.

Country Parliament
 Albania Kuvendi
 Bangladesh Jatiyo Sangshad
 Bulgaria National Assembly
 Botswana Parliament
 Burkina Faso National Assembly
 Croatia Sabor
 Denmark Folketing
 Dominica House of Assembly
 Estonia Riigikogu
 Finland Eduskunta/Riksdag
 Greece Hellenic Parliament
 Hungary National Assembly
 Iceland Althing
 Israel Knesset
 Kosovo Kuvendi
 Kuwait National Assembly of Kuwait
 Latvia Saeima
 Lebanon Assembly of Deputies
 Libya General National Congress
 Lithuania Seimas
 Luxembourg Chamber of Deputies
 Republic of Macedonia Sobranie
 Malta House of Representatives
 Mauritius National Assembly
 Moldova Parliament
 Mongolia State Great Khural
 Montenegro Parliament
 Nepal Nepalese Constituent Assembly
 New Zealand Parliament
 Norway Stortinget
 Papua New Guinea National Parliament
 Portugal Assembly of the Republic
 Saint Kitts and Nevis National Assembly
 Saint Vincent and the Grenadines House of Assembly
 Samoa Fono
 Serbia National Assembly
 Singapore Parliament
 Slovakia National Council
 Sri Lanka Parliament
 Sweden Riksdagen
 Turkey Grand National Assembly
 Ukraine Verkhovna Rada
 Vanuatu Parliament
 Kyrgyzstan Jogorku Kenesh

[edit] Bicameral system

This table shows organisations and countries with parliament consisting of two houses.

Organisation or Country Parliament Upper chamber Lower chamber
 Australia Parliament Senate House of Representatives
 Austria Parliament Federal Council National Council
 Antigua and Barbuda Parliament Senate House of Representatives
 The Bahamas Parliament Senate House of Assembly
 Barbados Parliament Senate House of Assembly
 Belarus National Assembly Council of the Republic House of Representatives
 Belize National Assembly Senate House of Representatives
 Belgium Federal Parliament Senate Chamber of Representatives
 Bhutan Parliament National Council National Assembly
 Cambodia Parliament Senate National Assembly
 Canada Parliament Senate House of Commons
 Czech Republic Parliament Senate Chamber of Deputies
 Ethiopia Federal Parliamentary Assembly House of Federation House of People's Representatives
 European Union Legislature of the European Union Council of the European Union European Parliament
 Germany Federal Legislature Bundesrat (Federal Council) Bundestag (Federal Diet)
 Grenada Parliament Senate House of Representatives
 India Parliament Rajya Sabha (Council of States) Lok Sabha (House of the People)
 Ireland Oireachtas Seanad Éireann Dáil Éireann
 Iraq Parliament Council of Union[4] Council of Representatives
 Italy Parliament Senate of the Republic Chamber of Deputies
 Jamaica Parliament Senate House of Representatives
 Japan Diet House of Councillors House of Representatives
 Malaysia Parliament Dewan Negara (Senate) Dewan Rakyat (House of Representatives)
 Netherlands Staten-Generaal (States-General) Eerste Kamer (Senate) Tweede Kamer (House of Representatives)
 Pakistan Parliament Senate Secretariat National Assembly Secretariat
 Poland Parliament Senate Sejm
 Saint Lucia Parliament Senate House of Assembly
 Slovenia Parliament National Council (only partially)[5] National Assembly
 South Africa Parliament National Council of Provinces National Assembly
 Spain Cortes Generales Senate Congress of Deputies
 Thailand National Assembly Senate House of Representatives
 Trinidad and Tobago Parliament Senate House of Representatives
 United Kingdom Parliament House of Lords House of Commons

[edit] See also

[edit] References

  1. ^ Lijphart, Arend (1999). Patterns of democracy. New Haven: Yale University Press.
  2. ^ T. St. John N. Bates (1986), "Parliament, Policy and Delegated Power", Statute Law Review (Oxford: Oxford University Press), http://slr.oxfordjournals.org/cgi/reprint/7/2/114.pdf
  3. ^ SSRN-Accountability and Corruption: Political Institutions Matter by Daniel Lederman, Norman Loayza, Rodrigo Soares
  4. ^ The Council of Union is defined in the constitution of Iraq but does not currently exist.
  5. ^ Lakota, Igor (2006) (in Slovene). Sistem nepopolne dvodomnosti v slovenskem parlamentu (diplomska naloga) [The system of incomplete bicameralism in the Slovenian Parliament (diploma thesis)]. Faculty of Social Sciences, University of Ljubljana. p. 59. http://dk.fdv.uni-lj.si/dela/Lakota-Igor.PDF. Retrieved 16 December 2010.