CBO Logo CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICEDouglas W. Elmendorf, Director

U.S. Congress

Washington, DC 20515


June 15, 2009

Honorable Edward M. Kennedy
Chairman
Committee on Health, Education,
Labor, and Pensions
United States Senate
Washington, DC 20510                  

Dear Mr. Chairman:

The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and the staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) have completed a preliminary analysis of the major provisions related to health insurance coverage that are contained in title I of draft legislation called the Affordable Health Choices Act, which was released by the Senate Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions (HELP) on June 9, 2009. Among other things, that draft legislation would establish insurance exchanges (called “gateways”) through which individuals and families could purchase coverage and would provide federal subsidies to substantially reduce the cost of that coverage for some enrollees.

The attached table summarizes our preliminary assessment of the proposal’s budgetary effects and its likely impact on insurance coverage. According to that assessment, enacting the proposal would result in a net increase in federal budget deficits of about $1.0 trillion over the 2010–2019 period. Once the proposal was fully implemented, about 39 million individuals would obtain coverage through the new insurance exchanges. At the same time, the number of people who had coverage through an employer would decline by about 15 million (or roughly 10 percent), and coverage from other sources would fall by about 8 million, so the net decrease in the number of people uninsured would be about 16 million.

It is important to note, however, that those figures do not represent a formal or complete cost estimate for the draft legislation, for reasons outlined below. Moreover, because expanded eligibility for the Medicaid program may be added at a later date, those figures are not likely to represent the impact that more comprehensive proposals—which might include a significant expansion of Medicaid or other options for subsidizing coverage for those with income below 150 percent of the federal poverty level—would have both on the federal budget and on the extent of insurance coverage.

Key Provisions Related to Health Insurance Coverage
Subtitles A through D of title I of the Affordable Health Choices Act would seek to increase the number of legal U.S. residents who have health insurance. Toward that end, the federal government would provide grants to states to establish insurance exchanges and—more importantly—would subsidize the purchase of health insurance through those exchanges for individuals and families with income between 150 percent and 500  percent of the federal poverty level; those subsidies would represent the greatest single component of the proposal’s cost. The proposal would also impose a financial cost on most people who do not obtain insurance, the size of which would be set by the Secretary of the Treasury.

The draft legislation released by the HELP Committee also indicates that certain features may be added at a later date. Because they are not reflected in the current draft, however, CBO and the JCT staff did not take them into account. In particular, the draft legislation does not contain provisions that would change the Medicaid program, although it envisions that the authority to extend Medicaid coverage will be added during Senate consideration of the bill. (By itself, adding such provisions would increase the proposal’s budgetary costs and would also yield a larger increase in the number of people who have health insurance.) The draft legislation also indicates that the committee is considering whether to incorporate other features, including a “public health insurance option” and requirements for “shared responsibility” by employers. Depending on their details, such provisions could also have substantial effects on our analysis. (A summary of the key provisions that were included in this analysis is attached.)

Important Caveats Regarding This Preliminary Analysis
There are several reasons why the preliminary analysis that is provided in this letter and its attachments does not constitute a comprehensive cost estimate for the Affordable Health Choices Act:

Likely Effects of the Proposal
The proposal would have significant effects on the number of people who are enrolled in health insurance plans, the sources of that coverage, and the federal budget.

Effects on Insurance Coverage. Under current law, the number of nonelderly residents (those under age 65) with health insurance coverage will grow from about 217 million in 2010 to about 228 million in 2019, according to CBO’s estimates. Over that same period, the number of nonelderly residents without health insurance at any given point in time will grow from approximately 50 million people to about 54 million people—constituting about 19 percent of the nonelderly population.2 Because the Medicare program covers nearly all legal residents over the age of 65, our analysis has focused on the effects of proposals on the nonelderly population.

People obtain insurance coverage from a variety of sources. Under current law, about 150 million nonelderly people will get their coverage through an employer in 2010, CBO estimates. Similarly, another 40 million people will be covered through the federal/state Medicaid program or the Children’s Health Insurance Program (CHIP). Other nonelderly people are covered by policies purchased individually in the “nongroup” market, or they obtain coverage from various other sources (including Medicare and the health benefit programs of the Department of Defense).

According to the preliminary analysis, once the proposal was fully implemented, the number of people who are uninsured would decline to about 36 million or 37 million, representing about 13 percent of the nonelderly population. (Roughly a third of those would be unauthorized immigrants or individuals who are eligible for Medicaid but not enrolled in that program.) That decline would be the net effect of several broad changes, which can be illustrated by examining the effects in a specific year. In 2017, for example, the number of uninsured would fall by about 16 million, relative to current-law projections. In that year, about 39 million people would be covered by policies purchased through the new insurance exchange. At the same time, about 147 million people would be covered by an employment-based health plan, 15 million fewer than under current law.3 Smaller net declines (totaling about 8 million) would occur in coverage under Medicaid and CHIP and in nongroup coverage because of the subsidies offered in the exchanges.

Budgetary Impact of Insurance Coverage Provisions. On a preliminary basis, CBO and the JCT staff estimate that the major provisions in title I of the Affordable Health Choices Act affecting health insurance coverage would result in a net increase in federal deficits of about $1.0 trillion for fiscal years 2010 through 2019. That estimate primarily reflects the subsidies that would be provided to purchase coverage through the new insurance exchanges, which would amount to nearly $1.3 trillion in that period. The average subsidy per exchange enrollee (including those who would receive no subsidy) would rise from roughly $5,000 in 2015 to roughly $6,000 in 2019. The other element of the proposal that would increase the federal deficit is a credit for small employers who offer health insurance, which is estimated to cost $60 billion over 10 years. Because a given firm would be allowed take the credit for only three consecutive years, the pattern of outlays would vary from year to year.

Those costs would be partly offset by receipts or savings from three sources: increases in tax revenues stemming from the decline in employment-based coverage; payments of penalties by uninsured individuals; and reductions in outlays for Medicaid and CHIP (relative to current-law projections).

The proposal would not change the tax treatment of health insurance premiums. Nevertheless, the reduction in the number of people receiving employment-based health insurance coverage, relative to current-law projections, would affect the government’s tax revenues. Because total compensation costs are determined by market forces, CBO and the JCT staff estimate that wages and other forms of compensation would rise by roughly the amounts of any reductions in employers’ health insurance costs. Employers’ payments for health insurance are tax-preferred, but most of those offsetting changes in compensation would come in the form of taxable wages and salaries. As a result, the shift in compensation brought about by the proposal would cause tax revenues to rise by $257 billion over 10 years. (Those figures are generally shown as negative numbers in the attached table because increases in revenues reduce the federal budget deficit.)

The government would also collect the payments that uninsured individuals would have to make. CBO and the JCT staff assume that the annual amount, which would be set by the Treasury Secretary, would be relatively small (about $100 per person). Moreover, individuals with income below 150 percent of the federal poverty level would not have to pay that amount. As a result, collections of those payments would total $2 billion over 10 years.

Finally, although the proposal would not change federal laws regarding Medicaid and CHIP, it would affect outlays for those programs. CBO assumes that states that had expanded eligibility for Medicaid and CHIP to people with income above 150 percent of the federal poverty level would be inclined to reverse those policies, because those individuals could instead obtain subsidies through the insurance exchanges that would be financed entirely by the federal government. Reflecting those reductions in enrollment, federal outlays for Medicaid and CHIP would decline by $38 billion over 10 years.

I hope this preliminary analysis is helpful for the committee’s consideration of the Affordable Health Choices Act. If you have any questions, please contact me or CBO staff. The primary staff contacts for this analysis are Philip Ellis and Holly Harvey.

Sincerely,

Douglas W. Elmendorf
Director

Attachments

cc: Honorable Michael B. Enzi
  Ranking Member

 


1. For a discussion of the considerations that affect whether and how various cash flows should be reflected in the federal budget, see Congressional Budget Office, The Budgetary Treatment of Proposals to Change the Nation’s Health Insurance System, Issue Brief (May 27, 2009).

2. Those estimates are “point-in-time” enrollment figures and thus represent annual averages. Also, some people have coverage from multiple sources at the same time (for example, Medicare and employment-based coverage), in which case they are assigned a primary source of coverage.

3. That net decline in employment-based coverage is itself the result of several flows. In particular, it includes roughly 10 million people who would have an offer of employment-based coverage but would be allowed to obtain subsidies in the insurance exchanges because that coverage would be deemed “unaffordable.” Although the legislation did not specify a standard for affordability, CBO and the JCT staff assumed that coverage would be deemed unaffordable if workers had to pay a larger share of their income for their employer’s plan than they would have to pay in the exchanges.



 

A Summary of the Key Provisions of
the HELP Committee’s Proposal
(As released on June 9, 2009)

Congressional Budget Office
June 15, 2009

 

Key Provisions Not Yet Taken Into Account

There are several features of the proposal that CBO and the JCT staff have not yet reflected in their budget estimates. The most significant features of the proposal that have not yet been estimated would do the following:

 


 

  Untitled Document
Preliminary Analysis of HELP Committee's Insurance Proposal  6/15/2009
NOTE: Figures in table do not reflect all elements of the proposal (see text)        
                         
   
 
EFFECTS ON COVERAGE OF NONELDERLY PEOPLEa 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019  
 
 
(Millions of people, by calendar year)                      
                         
Current Law Medicaid/CHIP 40 39 39 38 35 34 35 35 35 35  
Coverage Employer 150 153 156 158 161 162 162 162 162 162  
  Nongroup 13 12 12 12 13 14 14 14 14 15  
  Other 14 14 14 14 14 15 15 15 15 16  
  Uninsured 50 51 51 51 51 51 52 53 53 54  
  TOTAL 267 269 271 273 274 276 277 279 281 282  
                         
Change (+/-) Medicaid/CHIP -1 -1 * 1 -4 -3 -2 -2 -2 -2  
  Employer 2 2 -1 -7 -14 -14 -15 -15 -15 -15  
  Nongroup/Other * * -1 -2 -5 -5 -5 -6 -6 -6  
  Exchanges 0 0 5 17 38 38 38 39 39 40  
  Uninsured -1 -1 -3 -9 -15 -16 -16 -16 -17 -17  
                         
Post-Policy Uninsuredb Number of People 49 51 48 42 36 35 36 36 37 37  
  as a Share of Nonelderly 19% 19% 18% 15% 13% 13% 13% 13% 13% 13%  
                         
   
EFFECTS ON THE FEDERAL DEFICITa,c 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2010-
2019
 
(Billions of dollars, by fiscal year)                      
                         
Exchange Subsidies 0 0 17 66 148 183 196 209 223 237 1,279
Employer Subsidiesd 4 8 8 5 4 7 7 6 6 7 60
Payments by Uninsured Individuals 0 0 0 * * * * * * * -2
Medicaid/CHIP Outlays -1 -2 -1 2 -6 -7 -6 -6 -6 -6 -38
Tax Revenue Effects of Coverage Changese 1 2 -2 -15 -30 -37 -40 -43 -45 -48 -257
                         
NET IMPACT   4 7 21 58 116 146 157 166 177 189 1,042
                         
* = Less than 0.5 million people or spending/savings of less than $0.5 billion          
                         
Notes: a. Components may not sum to totals because of rounding.  b. The count of uninsured people includes unauthorized immigrants and people eligible for, but not enrolled in, Medicaid. c. Positive numbers indicate increases in the deficit, and negative numbers indicate reductions in the deficit.  d. The effects on the deficit from employer subsidies include their impact on taxable compensation. e. Increases in tax revenues reduce the deficit.
                         
Sources: Congressional Budget Office and Joint Committee on Taxation.