This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-04-951T 
entitled 'Energy Markets: Mergers and Many Other Factors Affect U.S. 
Gasoline Markets' which was released on July 07, 2004.

This text file was formatted by the U.S. General Accounting Office 
(GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part of a 
longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every 
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of 
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text 
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the 
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided 
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed 
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic 
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail 
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this 
document to Webmaster@gao.gov.

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work 
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the 
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this 
material separately.

Testimony:

Before the Subcommittee on Energy Policy, Natural Resources and 
Regulatory Affairs, Committee on Government Reform, House of 
Representatives:

United States General Accounting Office:

GAO:

For Release on Delivery Expected at 9:30 a.m. EDT:

Wednesday, July 7, 2004:

Energy Markets:

Mergers and Many Other Factors Affect U.S. Gasoline Markets:

Statement of Jim Wells, Director, Natural Resources and Environment:

GAO-04-951T:

GAO Highlights:

Highlights of GAO-04-951T, a report to Subcommittee on Energy Policy, 
Natural Resources and Regulatory Affairs, Committee on Government 
Reform, House of Representatives:  

Why GAO Did This Study:

Gasoline is subject to dramatic price swings. A multitude of factors 
cause volatility in U.S. gasoline markets, including world crude oil 
costs, limited refining capacity, and low inventories relative to 
demand.

Since the 1990s, another factor affecting U.S. gasoline markets has 
been a wave of mergers in the petroleum industry, several of them 
between large oil companies that had previously competed with each 
other. For example, in 1999, Exxon, the largest U.S. oil company, 
merged with Mobil, the second largest. 

This testimony is based primarily on Energy Markets: Effects of Mergers 
and Market Concentration in the U.S. Petroleum Industry (GAO-04-96, May 
17, 2004). This report examined mergers in the U.S. petroleum industry 
from the 1990s through 2000, the changes in market concentration (the 
distribution of market shares among competing firms) and other factors 
affecting competition in the U.S. petroleum industry, how U.S. gasoline 
marketing has changed since the 1990s, and how mergers and market 
concentration in the U.S. petroleum industry have affected U.S. 
gasoline prices at the wholesale level. 

To address these issues, GAO purchased and analyzed a large body of 
data and developed state-of-the art econometric models for isolating 
the effects of eight specific mergers and increased market 
concentration on wholesale gasoline prices. Experts peer-reviewed GAO’s 
analysis.

What GAO Found:

One of the many factors that can impact gasoline prices is mergers 
within the U.S. petroleum industry. Over 2,600 such mergers have 
occurred since the 1990s. The majority occurred later in the period, 
most frequently among firms involved in exploration and production. 
Industry officials cited various reasons for the mergers, particularly 
the need for increased efficiency and cost savings. Economic literature 
also suggests that firms sometimes merge to enhance their ability to 
control prices. 

Partly because of the mergers, market concentration has increased in 
the industry, mostly in the downstream (refining and marketing) 
segment. For example, market concentration in refining increased from 
moderately to highly concentrated on the East Coast and from 
unconcentrated to moderately concentrated on the West Coast. 
Concentration in the wholesale gasoline market increased substantially 
from the mid-1990s so that by 2002, most states had either moderately 
or highly concentrated wholesale gasoline markets. On the other hand, 
market concentration in the upstream (exploration and production) 
segment remained unconcentrated by the end of the 1990s. Anecdotal 
evidence suggests that mergers also have changed other factors 
affecting competition, such as firms’ ability to enter the market.

Two major changes have occurred in U.S. gasoline marketing related to 
mergers, according to industry officials. First, the availability of 
generic gasoline, which is generally priced lower than branded 
gasoline, has decreased substantially. Second, refiners now prefer to 
deal with large distributors and retailers, which has motivated 
further consolidation in distributor and retail markets.

Based on data from the mid-1990s through 2000, GAO’s econometric 
analyses indicate that mergers and increased market concentration 
generally led to higher wholesale gasoline prices in the United 
States. Six of the eight mergers GAO modeled led to price increases, 
averaging about 2 cents per gallon. Increased market concentration, 
which reflects the cumulative effects of mergers and other competitive 
factors, also led to increased prices in most cases. For conventional 
gasoline, the predominant type used in the country, the change in 
wholesale price due to increased market concentration ranged from a 
decrease of about 1 cent per gallon to an increase of about 5 cents per 
gallon. For boutique fuels sold in the East Coast and Gulf Coast 
regions, wholesale prices increased by about 1 cent per gallon, while 
prices for boutique fuels sold in California increased by over 7 cents 
per gallon. GAO also identified price increases of one-tenth of a cent 
to 7 cents that were caused by other factors included in the models—
particularly low gasoline inventories relative to demand, high refinery 
capacity utilization rates, and supply disruptions in some regions.

FTC disagreed with GAO’s methodology and findings. However, GAO 
believes its analyses are sound. 

www.gao.gov/cgi-bin/getrpt?GAO-04-951T.

To view the full product, including the scope and methodology, click on 
the link above. For more information, contact Jim Wells at (202) 
512-3841 or wellsj@gao.gov.

[End of section]

Mr. Chairman and Members of the Subcommittee:

We are pleased to be here today to participate in discussing issues 
related to the volatility of U.S. gasoline markets. According to data 
from the Energy Information Administration (EIA), the average 
nationwide price paid for regular gasoline (the type of gasoline used 
most in the United States) at the pump was as high as $2.06 cents/
gallon by the end of May 2004, an increase of about 58 cents/gallon or 
39 percent over the same time last year. On the West Coast, gasoline 
prices reached an average of $2.34 cents/gallon by the end of May 2004, 
an increase of about 65 cents/gallon or 38 percent over the same time 
last year. Although prices have recently begun to fall, elevated 
gasoline prices can be an economic burden to American consumers and the 
economy.

A broad range of factors affects the volatility of gasoline prices. 
These factors typically include changes in crude oil costs, limited 
refinery capacity, inventory levels relative to demand, supply 
disruptions, and regulatory factors--such as the many different 
gasoline formulations that are required to meet varying federal and 
state environmental laws. Federal and state taxes are also a component 
of U.S. gasoline prices, but these do not fluctuate often. We have 
addressed many of these issues in several studies on energy markets. 
Among other things, our past studies showed that:

* the U.S. economy is vulnerable to oil supply disruptions that can 
impose significant economic costs, and in our report options were 
identified to mitigate their effects;

* the Clean Air Act specifically requires refiners to produce 
reformulated gasoline, and the requirement to provide a specific blend 
for a specific area can present challenges to refiners and other 
suppliers if there are supply disruptions;

* gasoline price spikes were generally higher in California from 
January 1995 through December 1999 than in the rest of the nation, 
partly because of the difficulty in substituting for the loss of supply 
of CARB, the special reformulated gasoline used in California, when 
there were unplanned refinery outages;

* retail gasoline prices in California rose faster than they fell in 
response to a delayed pass-through in changes in the wholesale price of 
gasoline;

* as we testified in 2001, each day vehicles in the United States 
consume about 10 million barrels of petroleum fuels, primarily gasoline 
and diesel, and according to projections, the figure will rise to about 
15 million barrels per day by 2010, raising concerns about the nation's 
ability to satisfy this growing demand;

* the transportation sector is more than 90 percent dependent on 
petroleum-based fuels, such as gasoline, and this dependence 
contributes to our vulnerability to oil supply disruptions and related 
price shocks; and:

* existing federal programs to promote alternative fuel vehicles and 
alternative fuel use in the transportation sector have faced 
significant barriers.

Market consolidation is another factor that can affect the price of 
gasoline. Our testimony today will focus on our recent study that 
examined the effects of market consolidation and other factors on the 
U. S. petroleum industry.[Footnote 1]

Since the 1990s, the U.S. petroleum industry has experienced a wave of 
mergers, acquisitions, and joint ventures, several of them between 
large oil companies that had previously competed with each other for 
the sale of petroleum products.[Footnote 2] A few examples include the 
merger between British Petroleum (BP) and Amoco in 1998 to form 
BPAmoco, which later merged with ARCO, and the merger in 1999 between 
Exxon, the largest U.S. oil company, and Mobil, the second largest. In 
general, mergers raise concerns about potential anticompetitive effects 
on the U.S. petroleum industry and ultimately on gasoline prices 
because mergers could result in greater market power for the merged 
companies, potentially allowing them to increase prices above 
competitive levels.[Footnote 3] On the other hand, mergers could also 
yield cost savings and efficiency gains, which may be passed on to 
consumers in lower prices. Ultimately, the impact depends on whether 
market power or efficiency dominates.

Our report examined mergers in the U.S. petroleum industry from the 
1990s through 2000, the changes in market concentration (the 
distribution of market shares among competing firms) and other factors 
affecting competition in the U.S. petroleum industry, how U.S. gasoline 
marketing has changed since the 1990s, and how mergers and market 
concentration in the U.S. petroleum industry have affected U.S. 
gasoline prices at the wholesale level.

To address these issues, we purchased and analyzed a large body of data 
on mergers and wholesale gasoline prices, as well as data on other 
relevant economic factors. We also developed econometric models for 
examining the effects of eight specific mergers and increased market 
concentration on U.S. wholesale gasoline prices nationwide. It is 
noteworthy that using econometric models allowed us to measure the 
effects of mergers and market concentration while isolating the effects 
of several other factors that could influence wholesale gasoline 
prices, such as world crude oil costs, limited refining capacity, or 
low inventories relative to demand.

In the course of our work, we consulted with Dr. Severin 
Borenstein,[Footnote 4] a recognized expert in the modeling of gasoline 
markets; interviewed officials across the industry spectrum; and 
reviewed relevant economic literature and numerous related studies. We 
also used an extensive peer review process to obtain comments from 
experts in academia and relevant government agencies. We conducted our 
work in accordance with generally accepted government auditing 
standards.

In summary, we found the following:

* Over 2,600 mergers occurred in the petroleum industry from 1991 
through 2000. The majority of the mergers occurred during the second 
half of the decade, most frequently in the upstream (exploration and 
production) segment of the industry. Petroleum industry officials cited 
various reasons for this wave of mergers, particularly the need for 
increased efficiency and cost savings. Economic literature suggests 
that firms also sometimes use mergers to enhance their market power. 
Ultimately, the reasons cited by both sources generally relate to the 
merging companies' desire to maximize profit or shareholder wealth.

* Market concentration, which is commonly measured by the Herfindahl-
Hirschman Index (HHI), has increased in the downstream (refining and 
marketing) segment of the U.S. petroleum industry since the 1990s, 
partly as a result of merger activities, while changing very little in 
the upstream (exploration and production) segment. In the downstream 
segment, market concentration in refining increased from moderately to 
highly concentrated on the East Coast and from unconcentrated to 
moderately concentrated on the West Coast; it increased but remained 
moderately concentrated in the Rocky Mountain region. Concentration in 
the wholesale gasoline market increased substantially from the mid-
1990s so that by 2002, most states had either moderately or highly 
concentrated wholesale gasoline markets. On the other hand, market 
concentration decreased somewhat in the upstream segment and remained 
unconcentrated by the end of the 1990s. Anecdotal evidence suggests 
that mergers also have affected other factors that impact competition, 
such as the ability of new firms to enter the market.

* According to industry officials, two major changes have occurred in 
U.S. gasoline marketing since the 1990s, partly related to mergers. 
First, the availability of unbranded (generic) gasoline has decreased 
substantially. Unbranded gasoline is generally priced lower than 
branded gasoline, which is marketed under the refiner's trademark. 
Industry officials generally attributed the decreased availability of 
unbranded gasoline to, among other factors, a reduction in the number 
of independent refiners that typically supply unbranded gasoline. 
Second, industry officials said that refiners now prefer dealing with 
large distributors and retailers. This preference, according to the 
officials, has motivated further consolidation in both the distributor 
and retail markets, including the rise of hypermarkets--a relatively 
new breed of gasoline market participants that includes such large 
retail warehouses as Wal-Mart and Costco.

* Our econometric analyses, using data from the mid-1990s through 2000, 
show that oil industry mergers generally led to higher wholesale 
gasoline prices (measured in our report as wholesale prices less crude 
oil prices), although prices sometimes decreased. Six of the eight 
specific mergers we modeled--which mostly involved large, fully 
vertically integrated companies--generally resulted in increases in 
wholesale prices for branded and/or unbranded gasoline of about 2 cents 
per gallon, on average. Two of the mergers generally led to price 
decreases, of about 1 cent per gallon, on average. For conventional 
gasoline--the predominant type used in the United States except in 
areas that require special gasoline formulations--the change in 
wholesale price ranged from a decrease of about 1 cent per gallon to an 
increase of about 5 cents per gallon. The preponderance of price 
increases over decreases indicates that the market power effects, which 
tend to increase prices, for the most part outweighed the efficiency 
effects, which tend to decrease prices.

* Our econometric analyses also show that increased market 
concentration, which captures the cumulative effects of mergers as well 
as other market structure factors, also generally led to higher prices 
for conventional gasoline and for boutique fuels--gasoline that has 
been reformulated for certain areas in the East Coast and Gulf Coast 
regions and in California to lower pollution. The price increases were 
particularly large in California, where they averaged about 7 cents per 
gallon. Higher wholesale gasoline prices were also a result of other 
factors: low gasoline inventories, which typically occur in the summer 
driving months; high refinery capacity utilization rates; and supply 
disruptions, which occurred in the Midwest and on the West Coast.

* We also identified price increases of one-tenth of 1 cent to 7 cents 
per gallon that were caused by other factors included in our models--
particularly low gasoline inventories relative to demand, high refinery 
capacity utilization rates, and supply disruptions that occurred in 
some regions.

As I noted earlier, we used extensive peer review to obtain comments 
from outside experts, including the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and 
EIA, and we incorporated those comments as appropriate. FTC disagreed 
with our methodology and findings and provided extensive comments, 
which we have addressed in our report. Our findings are generally 
consistent with previous studies of the effects of specific oil mergers 
and of market concentration on gasoline prices. We believe, however, 
that ours is the first comprehensive study to model the impact of the 
industry's 1990s wave of mergers on wholesale gasoline prices for the 
entire United States, an effort that required us to acquire large 
datasets and perform complex analyses.

Background:

Many firms of varying sizes make up the U.S. petroleum industry. While 
some firms engage in only limited activities within the industry, such 
as exploration for and production of crude oil and natural gas or 
refining crude oil and marketing petroleum products, fully vertically 
integrated oil companies participate in all aspects of the industry. 
Before the 1970s, major oil companies that were fully vertically 
integrated controlled the global network for supplying, pricing, and 
marketing crude oil. However, the structure of the world crude oil 
market has dramatically changed as a result of such factors as the 
nationalization of oil fields by oil-producing countries, the emergence 
of independent oil companies, and the evolution of futures and spot 
markets in the 1970s and 1980s. Since U.S. oil prices were deregulated 
in 1981, the price paid for crude oil in the United States has been 
largely determined in the world oil market, which is mostly influenced 
by global factors, especially supply decisions of the Organization of 
Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) and world economic and political 
conditions.

The United States currently imports over 60 percent of its crude oil 
supply. In contrast, the bulk of the gasoline used in the United States 
is produced domestically. In 2001, for example, gasoline refined in the 
United States accounted for over 90 percent of the total domestic 
gasoline consumption. Companies that supply gasoline to U.S. markets 
also post the domestic gasoline prices. Historically, the domestic 
petroleum market has been divided into five regions: the East Coast 
region, the Midwest region, the Gulf Coast region, the Rocky Mountain 
region, and the West Coast region.[Footnote 5]

Proposed mergers in all industries, including the petroleum industry, 
are generally reviewed by federal antitrust authorities--including FTC 
and the Department of Justice (DOJ)--to assess the potential impact on 
market competition. According to FTC officials, FTC generally reviews 
proposed mergers involving the petroleum industry because of the 
agency's expertise in that industry. FTC analyzes these mergers to 
determine if they would likely diminish competition in the relevant 
markets and result in harm, such as increased prices. To determine the 
potential effect of a merger on market competition, FTC evaluates how 
the merger would change the level of market concentration, among other 
things. Conceptually, the higher the concentration, the less 
competitive the market is and the more likely that firms can exert 
control over prices. The ability to maintain prices above competitive 
levels for a significant period of time is known as market power.

According to the merger guidelines jointly issued by DOJ and FTC, 
market concentration as measured by HHI is ranked into three separate 
categories: a market with an HHI under 1,000 is considered to be 
unconcentrated; if HHI is between 1,000 and 1,800 the market is 
considered moderately concentrated; and if HHI is above 1,800, the 
market is considered highly concentrated. [Footnote 6]

While concentration is an important aspect of market structure--the 
underlying economic and technical characteristics of an industry--other 
aspects of market structure that may be affected by mergers also play 
an important role in determining the level of competition in a market. 
These aspects include barriers to entry, which are market conditions 
that provide established sellers an advantage over potential new 
entrants in an industry, and vertical integration.

Mergers Occurred in All Segments of the U.S. Petroleum Industry in the 
1990s for Several Reasons:

Over 2,600 merger transactions occurred from 1991 through 2000 
involving all three segments of the U.S. petroleum industry. Almost 85 
percent of the mergers occurred in the upstream segment (exploration 
and production), while the downstream segment (refining and marketing 
of petroleum) accounted for about 13 percent, and the midstream segment 
(transportation) accounted for over 2 percent. The vast majority of the 
mergers--about 80 percent--involved one company's purchase of a segment 
or asset of another company, while about 20 percent involved the 
acquisition of a company's total assets by another so that the two 
became one company. Most of the mergers occurred in the second half of 
the decade, including those involving large partially or fully 
vertically integrated companies.

Petroleum industry officials and experts we contacted cited several 
reasons for the industry's wave of mergers in the 1990s, including 
achieving synergies, increasing growth and diversifying assets, and 
reducing costs. Economic literature indicates that enhancing market 
power is also sometimes a motive for mergers. Ultimately, these reasons 
mostly relate to companies' desire to maximize profit or stock values.

Mergers Contributed to Increases in Market Concentration and to Other 
Changes That Affect Competition:

Mergers in the 1990s contributed to increases in market concentration 
in the downstream segment of the U.S. petroleum industry, while the 
upstream segment experienced little change overall. We found that 
market concentration, as measured by the HHI, decreased slightly in the 
upstream segment, based on crude oil production activities at the 
national level, from 290 in 1990 to 217 in 2000. Moreover, based on 
benchmarks established jointly by DOJ and FTC, the upstream segment of 
the U.S. petroleum industry remained unconcentrated at the end of the 
1990s.

The increases in market concentration in the downstream segment varied 
by activity and region.

* For example, the HHI of the refining market in the East Coast region 
increased from a moderately concentrated level of 1136 in 1990 to a 
highly concentrated level of 1819 in 2000. In the Rocky Mountain and 
the West Coast regions, it increased from 1029 to 1124 and from 937 to 
1267, respectively, in that same period. Thus, while each of these 
refining markets increased in concentration, the Rocky Mountain 
remained within the moderately concentrated range but the West Coast 
changed from unconcentrated in 1990 to moderately concentrated in 2000. 
The HHI of refining markets also increased from 699 to 980 in the 
Midwest and from 534 to 704 in the Gulf Coast during the same period, 
although these markets remained unconcentrated.

* In wholesale gasoline markets, market concentration increased broadly 
throughout the United States between 1994 and 2002. Specifically, we 
found that 46 states and the District of Columbia had moderately or 
highly concentrated markets by 2002, compared to 27 in 1994.

In both the refining and wholesale markets of the downstream segment, 
merger activity and market concentration were highly correlated for 
most regions of the country.

Evidence from various sources indicates that, in addition to increasing 
market concentration, mergers also contributed to changes in other 
aspects of market structure in the U.S. petroleum industry that affect 
competition--specifically, vertical integration and barriers to entry. 
However, we could not quantify the extent of these changes because of a 
lack of relevant data.

Vertical integration can conceptually have both pro-and anticompetitive 
effects. Based on anecdotal evidence and economic analyses by some 
industry experts, we determined that a number of mergers that have 
occurred since the 1990s have led to greater vertical integration in 
the U.S. petroleum industry, especially in the refining and marketing 
segment. For example, we identified eight mergers that occurred between 
1995 and 2001 that might have enhanced the degree of vertical 
integration, particularly in the downstream segment.

Concerning barriers to entry, our interviews with petroleum industry 
officials and experts provide evidence that mergers had some impact on 
the U.S. petroleum industry. Barriers to entry could have implications 
for market competition because companies that operate in concentrated 
industries with high barriers to entry are more likely to possess 
market power. Industry officials pointed out that large capital 
requirements and environmental regulations constitute barriers for 
potential new entrants into the U.S. refining business. For example, 
the officials indicated that a typical refinery could cost billions of 
dollars to build and that it may be difficult to obtain the necessary 
permits from the relevant state or local authorities. At the wholesale 
and retail marketing levels, industry officials pointed out that 
mergers might have exacerbated barriers to entry in some markets. For 
example, the officials noted that mergers have contributed to a 
situation where pipelines and terminals are owned by fewer, mostly 
integrated companies that sometimes deny access to third-party users, 
especially when supply is tight--which creates a disincentive for 
potential new entrants into such wholesale markets.

U.S. Gasoline Marketing Has Changed in Two Major Ways:

According to some petroleum industry officials that we interviewed, 
gasoline marketing in the United States has changed in two major ways 
since the 1990s. First, the availability of unbranded gasoline has 
decreased, partly due to mergers. Officials noted that unbranded 
gasoline is generally priced lower than branded. They generally 
attributed the decreased availability of unbranded gasoline to one or 
more of the following factors:

* There are now fewer independent refiners, who typically supply mostly 
unbranded gasoline. These refiners have been acquired by branded 
companies, have grown large enough to be considered a brand, or have 
simply closed down.

* Partially or fully vertically integrated oil companies have sold or 
mothballed some refineries. As a result, some of these companies now 
have only enough refinery capacity to supply their own branded needs, 
with little or no excess to sell as unbranded.

* Major branded refiners are managing their inventory more efficiently, 
ensuring that they produce only enough gasoline to meet their current 
branded needs.

We could not quantify the extent of the decrease in the unbranded 
gasoline supply because the data required for such analyses do not 
exist.

The second change identified by these officials is that refiners now 
prefer dealing with large distributors and retailers because they 
present a lower credit risk and because it is more efficient to sell a 
larger volume through fewer entities. Refiners manifest this preference 
by setting minimum volume requirements for gasoline purchases. These 
requirements have motivated further consolidation in the distributor 
and retail sectors, including the rise of hypermarkets.

Mergers and Increased Market Concentration Generally Led to Higher U.S. 
Wholesale Gasoline Prices:

Our econometric modeling shows that the mergers we examined mostly led 
to higher wholesale gasoline prices in the second half of the 1990s. 
The majority of the eight specific mergers we examined--Ultramar 
Diamond Shamrock (UDS)-Total, Tosco-Unocal, Marathon-Ashland, Shell-
Texaco I (Equilon), Shell-Texaco II (Motiva), BP-Amoco, Exxon-Mobil, 
and Marathon Ashland Petroleum (MAP)-UDS--resulted in higher prices of 
wholesale gasoline in the cities where the merging companies supplied 
gasoline before they merged. The effects of some of the mergers were 
inconclusive, especially for boutique fuels sold in the East Coast and 
Gulf Coast regions and in California.

* For the seven mergers that we modeled for conventional gasoline, five 
led to increased prices, especially the MAP-UDS and Exxon-Mobil 
mergers, where the increases generally exceeded 2 cents per gallon, on 
average.

* For the four mergers that we modeled for reformulated gasoline, two-
-Exxon-Mobil and Marathon-Ashland--led to increased prices of about 1 
cent per gallon, on average. In contrast, the Shell-Texaco II (Motiva) 
merger led to price decreases of less than one-half cent per gallon, on 
average, for branded gasoline only.

* For the two mergers--Tosco-Unocal and Shell-Texaco I (Equilon)--that 
we modeled for gasoline used in California, known as California Air 
Resources Board (CARB) gasoline, only the Tosco-Unocal merger led to 
price increases. The increases were for branded gasoline only and 
exceeded 6 cents per gallon, on average.

For market concentration, which captures the cumulative effects of 
mergers as well as other competitive factors, our econometric analysis 
shows that increased market concentration resulted in higher wholesale 
gasoline prices.

* Prices for conventional (non-boutique) gasoline, the dominant type of 
gasoline sold nationwide from 1994 through 2000, increased by less than 
one-half cent per gallon, on average, for branded and unbranded 
gasoline. The increases were larger in the West than in the East--the 
increases were between one-half cent and one cent per gallon in the 
West, and about one-quarter cent in the East (for branded gasoline 
only), on average.

* Price increases for boutique fuels sold in some parts of the East 
Coast and Gulf Coast regions and in California were larger compared to 
the increases for conventional gasoline. The wholesale prices increased 
by an average of about 1 cent per gallon for boutique fuel sold in the 
East Coast and Gulf Coast regions between 1995 and 2000, and by an 
average of over 7 cents per gallon in California between 1996 and 2000.

Our analysis shows that wholesale gasoline prices were also affected by 
other factors included in the econometric models--particularly, 
gasoline inventories relative to demand, refinery capacity utilization 
rates, and the supply disruptions that occurred in some parts of the 
Midwest and the West Coast. In particular, wholesale gasoline prices 
were about 1 cent per gallon higher, on average, when gasoline 
inventories were low relative to demand, typically in the summer 
driving months. Also, prices were higher by about an average of one-
tenth to two-tenths of 1 cent per gallon when refinery capacity 
utilization rates increased by 1 percent. The prices of conventional 
gasoline were about 4 to 5 cents per gallon higher, on average, during 
the Midwest and West Coast supply disruptions. The increase in prices 
for CARB gasoline was about 4 to 7 cents per gallon, on average, during 
the West Coast supply disruptions.

Mr. Chairman, this concludes my prepared statement. I would be happy to 
respond to any questions that you or other Members of the Subcommittee 
may have.

GAO Contact and Staff Acknowledgments:

For further information about this testimony, please contact me at 
(202) 512-3841. Key contributors to this testimony included Godwin 
Agbara, Scott Farrow, John A. Karikari, and Cynthia Norris.

FOOTNOTES

[1] See U.S. General Accounting Office, Energy Markets: Effects of 
Mergers and Market Concentration in the U.S. Petroleum Industry, 
GAO-04-96 (Washington, D.C., May 17, 2004). Additional related GAO 
studies include U.S. Ethanol Market: MTBE Ban in California, 
GAO-02-440R (Washington, D.C., Feb. 27, 2002); Alternative Motor Fuels 
and Vehicles: Impact on the Transportation Sector, GAO-01-957T 
(Washington, D.C., July 10, 2001); Motor Fuels: California Gasoline 
Price Behavior, GAO/RCED-96-121 (Washington, D.C., Apr. 28, 2000); 
International Energy Agency: How the Agency Prepares Its World Market 
Statistics, GAO/RCED-99-142 (Washington, D.C., May 7, 1999); and Energy 
Security: Evaluating U.S. Vulnerability to Oil Supply Disruptions and 
Options for Mitigating Their Effects, GAO/RCED-97-6 (Washington, D.C., 
Dec. 12, 1996).

[2] We refer to all of these transactions as mergers.

[3] The Federal Trade Commission and Department of Justice have defined 
market power for a seller as the ability to profitably maintain prices 
above competitive levels for a significant period of time.

[4] Dr. Borenstein is E.T. Grether Professor of Business Administration 
and Public Policy at the Haas School of Business, University of 
California, Berkeley. He is also the Director of the University of 
California Energy Institute.

[5] These regions are known as Petroleum Administration for Defense 
Districts (PADDs).

[6] HHI is calculated by summing the squares of the market shares of 
all the firms within a given market.