This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-09-724R 
entitled 'Climate Change Trade Measures: Considerations for U.S. Policy 
Makers' which was released on July 8, 2009. 

This text file was formatted by the U.S. Government Accountability 
Office (GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part 
of a longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every 
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of 
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text 
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the 
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided 
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed 
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic 
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail 
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this 
document to Webmaster@gao.gov. 

This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright 
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed 
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work 
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the 
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this 
material separately. 

United States Government Accountability Office: 
Washington, DC 20548: 

July 8, 2009: 

The Honorable Max Baucus:
Committee on Finance, Chairman:
United States Senate: 

Subject: Climate Change Trade Measures: Considerations for U.S. Policy 
Makers: 

Dear Mr. Chairman: 

Changes in the earth's climate attributable to increased concentrations 
of greenhouse gases may have significant environmental and economic 
impacts in the United States and internationally. To mitigate climate 
change effects, countries are taking or considering varying approaches 
to reducing greenhouse gas emissions, such as carbon dioxide, which is 
the most important greenhouse gas due to its significant volume. These 
approaches range from measures to increase energy efficiency to longer- 
term efforts to develop technologies to establish a less carbon- 
intensive energy infrastructure. A U.S. policy to mitigate climate 
change may require domestic production facilities to achieve specified 
reductions or employ a market-based mechanism, such as establishing a 
price on emissions. 

Between 2007 and 2009, Congress introduced a number of climate change 
bills, many of which contained proposals for a domestic emissions 
pricing system, such as a cap-and-trade system[Footnote 1] or a carbon 
tax[Footnote 2]. Through greenhouse gas emissions pricing, governments 
create an incentive for parties to lower their greenhouse gas emissions 
by placing a cost on them. However, imposing costs on energy-intensive 
industries in the United States could potentially place them at a 
disadvantage to foreign competitors. In addition, emissions pricing 
could have negative environmental consequences, such as "carbon 
leakage," whereby emissions reductions in the United States are 
replaced by increases in production and emissions in less-regulated 
countries. As the Congress considers the design of a domestic emissions 
pricing system, a key challenge will be balancing the need to reduce 
greenhouse gas emissions with the need to address the competitiveness 
of U.S. industries. 

In anticipation of Senate deliberation on climate change legislative 
proposals, you asked us to examine how greenhouse gas emissions pricing 
could potentially affect the international competitiveness of U.S. 
industries, and to examine trade measures being considered as part of 
proposed U.S. climate change legislation.[Footnote 3] On July 6, 2009, 
we briefed your staff covering: (1) what is known about estimating 
industry effects, (2) examples of industries that may be vulnerable to 
a loss in international competitiveness from emissions pricing, (3) 
trade measures and other approaches to address competitiveness issues, 
and (4) the potential international implications of trade measures. A 
copy of the slides presented at the briefing is attached. 

To address these objectives, we interviewed officials and reviewed 
climate change literature and documents from relevant federal agencies, 
international organizations, policy institutes, businesses, 
professional organizations, and universities; reviewed and analyzed 
climate change legislation introduced between 2007 and 2009 and 
congressional hearing records; we reviewed and presented summary 
results for two studies that attempt to quantify the potential 
international competitiveness effects on domestic industries from 
greenhouse gas emissions pricing; and conducted interviews with 
officials from the embassies of Australia, Brazil, Canada, China, the 
European Union, and Mexico. We conducted our work from October 2008 to 
July 2009 in accordance with all sections of GAO's Quality Assurance 
Framework that are relevant to our objectives. The framework requires 
that we plan and perform the engagement to obtain sufficient and 
appropriate evidence to meet our stated objectives and to discuss any 
limitations in our work. We believe that the information and data 
obtained, and the analysis conducted, provide a reasonable basis for 
any findings and conclusions in this product. For additional details 
regarding our scope and methodology, see appendix I. 

We are sending copies of this report to interested congressional 
committees and to other parties. In addition, the report will be 
available at no charge on GAO's Web site at [hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov]. 

If you or your staff have any questions or wish to discuss this 
material further, please contact me at (202) 512-4347 or 
yagerl@gao.gov. Contact points for our Offices of Congressional 
Relations and Public Affairs may be found on the last page of this 
report. Christine Broderick (Assistant Director), Etana Finkler, 
Kendall Helm, Jeremy Latimer, Maria Mercado, and Ardith Spence, made 
significant contributions to this report. In addition, Karen Deans, 
David Dornisch, Grace Lui, and Jena Sinkfield provided technical 
assistance. 

Sincerely yours, 

Signed by: 

Loren Yager:
Director, International Affairs and Trade: 

[End of section] 

Climate Change Trade Measures: Considerations for U.S. Policy Makers: 

July 2009: 

Why GAO Did This Study: 

Global climate change is one of the most significant long-term policy 
challenges facing the United States, and policies to mitigate climate 
change will have important economic, social, and environmental 
implications. 

Members of Congress have introduced several bills to address the 
problem of climate change, many of which establish domestic emissions 
pricing by requiring firms that emit greenhouse gases either to pay a 
tax or to hold emission allowances. Whichever approach is taken, 
domestic emissions pricing could produce environmental benefits by 
encouraging U.S. firms to reduce their emissions of greenhouse gases. 
But such pricing could also harm U.S. firms' competitiveness, 
especially in energy-intensive industries where firms compete 
internationally. Additionally, there could be increased emissions 
abroad if production were to increase in other countries as a result of 
increased domestic costs of production resulting from a U.S. climate 
policy (carbon leakage). To help reduce impacts on U.S. firms and 
prevent carbon leakage, several climate change bills have also included 
trade measures or output-based rebates. The bills have included trade 
measures that would require importers to purchase emission allowances 
or pay a border tax for the greenhouse gas emissions associated with 
their imports. They have also designed output-based rebates to 
financially rebate industries for the costs incurred under a domestic 
emissions pricing system. 

Briefing Structure: 

Background (slides 3-4): 

Section 1: Estimating Industry Effects (slides 5-10): 

Section 2: Potentially Vulnerable Industries (slides 11-20): 

Section 3: Trade Measures (slides 21-31): 

Section 4: International Trade Implications (slides 32-35): 

Appendices (slides 36-46): 

Estimating Industry Effects: Estimating the potential effects of 
domestic emissions pricing for industries in the United States is 
complex. If the United States were to regulate greenhouse gas 
emissions, production costs could rise for certain industries and could 
cause output, profits, or employment to fall. Within these industries, 
some of these adverse effects could arise through an increase in 
imports, a decrease in exports, or both. Estimates of adverse 
competitiveness effects are generally larger for industries that are 
both relatively energy and trade intensive. In 2007, these industries 
accounted for about 4.5 percent of domestic output. 

Estimates of the effects vary because of key assumptions required by 
economic models. For example, models generally assume a price for U.S. 
carbon emissions, but do not assume a similar price by other nations. 
In addition, the models generally do not incorporate all policy 
provisions, such as legislative proposals related to trade measures and 
rebates that are based on levels of production. 

Potentially Vulnerable Industries: Proposed legislation suggests that 
industries vulnerable to competitiveness effects should be considered 
differently. Industries for which competitiveness measures would apply 
are identified on the basis of their energy and trade intensity. Most 
of the industries that meet these criteria are in primary metals, 
nonmetallic minerals, paper, and chemicals, although significant 
variation exists for product groups (sub-industries) within each 
industry. Additional variation arises on the basis of the type of 
energy used and the extent to which foreign competitors' greenhouse gas 
emissions are regulated. 

To illustrate variability in characteristics that make industries 
vulnerable to competitiveness effects, we selected example sub- 
industries within primary metals, non metallic minerals, paper 
products, and chemicals based on multiple factors. For example, we 
selected sub-industries that met both the energy and trade intensity 
criteria, examples that met only one criterion, and examples that met 
neither, but had significant imports from countries without greenhouse- 
gas pricing. 

Trade Measures: Trade measures have been proposed to help address 
potential industry and environmental effects of a domestic emissions 
pricing system; however, questions exist about their proposed 
effectiveness. Supporters argue that trade measures may help prevent a 
decline in output by U.S. producers, prevent carbon leakage, and create 
leverage for other countries to reduce emissions. Opponents raise 
concerns that trade measures may motivate retaliatory actions, 
undermine efforts to secure multilateral consensus, and generate little 
leverage. In addition, potential implementation challenges may exist. 

Output-based rebates are measures that offset incurred costs to 
industries due to emissions pricing and can take the form of a per-unit 
rebate, allocation of allowances or tax credit. These rebates have been 
proposed to address competitiveness effects; however, limitations with 
these measures may also exist. For example, output-based rebates may 
increase costs for industries that do not receive them, under certain 
conditions. 

How a trade measure is ultimately designed will have important 
implications for the effectiveness of the overall measure in addressing 
industry and environmental effects. For example, delaying the timing 
for when the trade measure goes into effect could result in the measure 
being a more effective leveraging tool, and would provide other 
countries an opportunity to implement similar carbon mitigation 
policies to reduce global emissions. On the other hand, having the 
trade measure go into effect simultaneously when the domestic cap-and- 
trade system goes into effect may reduce impacts on U.S. industry 
competitiveness. 

International Trade Implications: A unilateral U.S. trade measure could 
have important international implications on U.S. bilateral and 
multilateral trade relations. For example, other countries could view 
U.S. trade measures as trade restrictions or sanctions, which could 
lead them to implement restrictions against U.S. exports. Attention 
also has focused on the potential for trade measures or output-based 
rebates to be challenged under World Trade Organization (WTO) rules. 

Assessing the international trade implications is difficult for a 
number of reasons. One is that it depends in part upon how other 
nations reduce their carbon emissions, and whether they perceive any 
U.S. measures as likely to affect their exports. In addition, the 
outcome of any WTO challenge, if any, would be uncertain and may depend 
on how the measure is implemented. 

Objectives, Scope, and Methodology: 

GAO was asked to examine the potential effects of greenhouse gas 
emissions pricing on U.S. industries' international competitiveness and 
trade measures being considered as part of U.S. legislative proposals 
to address climate change. 

Specifically, we examined: (1) what is known about estimating industry 
effects; (2) examples of industries that may be vulnerable to a loss in 
international competitiveness from emissions pricing; (3) trade 
measures and other approaches to address competitiveness issues; and 
(4) potential international implications of trade measures. 

To address these objectives, we interviewed officials and reviewed 
climate change literature and documents from U.S. agencies, 
international organizations, policy institutes, and professional 
organizations; reviewed and analyzed climate change legislation 
introduced between 2007 and 2009 and congressional hearing records; 
reviewed and presented summary results for two studies attempting to 
quantify the potential international competitiveness effects on 
domestic industries from emissions pricing; and conducted interviews 
with officials from the embassies of Australia, Brazil, Canada, China, 
the European Union, and Mexico. 

The Office of the United States Trade Representative provided technical 
comments on this report. 

The analysis in this report reflects changes to the American Clean 
Energy and Security Act of 2009 (HR 2454), as of June 26, 2009. 

For additional details regarding our scope and methodology, see 
appendix I. 

[End of section] 

Background: Greenhouse Gas Emissions: 

The Greenhouse Effect: 

Greenhouse gases, such as carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, and 
other gases, increase temperatures by trapping heat that would 
otherwise escape the earth's atmosphere. The heat-trapping effect, 
known as the greenhouse effect, moderates atmospheric temperatures, 
keeping the earth warm enough to support life. Although each unit of 
non-carbon-dioxide greenhouse gas generally has a greater warming 
effect than each unit of carbon dioxide, carbon dioxide is the most 
important greenhouse gas because of its significant volume. The potency 
of other greenhouse gases may be expressed in terms of their warming 
potential relative to carbon dioxide, or their carbon dioxide 
equivalent. 

Estimated Growth in Emissions: 

According to the IPCC, in 2004, developed countries, including the 
United States, constituted 20 percent of the global population, but 
were responsible for nearly half of global greenhouse gas emissions. 
However, the IPCC projects that between 2000 and 2030, two-thirds to 
three-quarters of the projected increase in global carbon dioxide 
emissions will occur in developing countries. The IPCC also projects 
that compared with 2000, global greenhouse gas emissions will increase 
between 25 percent and 90 percent by 2030 in the absence of policies to 
reduce greenhouse gas emissions worldwide. 

The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) was established to 
provide scientific and objective information on climate change. 
According to the IPCC, global atmospheric concentrations of greenhouse 
gases have increased markedly as a result of human activities over the 
past 200 years, contributing to a warming of the earth's climate. 
Climate change is a long-term and global issue because greenhouse gases 
disperse widely in the atmosphere once emitted and can remain there for 
an extended period of time. Among other potential impacts, climate 
change could threaten coastal areas with rising sea levels, alter 
agricultural productivity, and increase the intensity and frequency of 
floods and tropical storms. While the effect of increases in greenhouse 
gas emissions on ecosystems and economic growth is expected to vary 
across regions, countries, and economic sectors, a panel of 18 climate 
change economists convened by GAO in coordination with the National 
Academy of Sciences agreed that the Congress should consider using a 
market-based mechanism to place a price on emissions, and 14 of the 18 
panelists were at least moderately confident that the benefits of 
taking these actions would outweigh the costs. See GAO-08-605. 

As shown in figure 1, the United States emitted more carbon dioxide 
than any other country in 2006, while China recently surpassed the 
European countries that are members of the Organization for Economic 
Cooperation and Development (OECD) as the world's second largest 
emitter. On a per capita basis, the United States and Canada rank first 
and second in carbon dioxide emissions. Between 1990 and 2006, carbon 
dioxide emissions grew substantially in both China and India. 

Figure 1: Data on Global Carbon Dioxide Emissions (Millions of metric 
tons): 

[Refer to PDF for image: combined line and vertical bar graph] 

United States: 
1995 Emissions: 5133.3; 
2006 Emissions: 5696.8; 
2006 Emissions per Capita: 19. 

China: 
1995 Emissions: 3021.8; 
2006 Emissions: 5648.5; 
2006 Emissions per Capita: 4.28. 

OECD Europe: 
1995 Emissions: 3856.4; 
2006 Emissions: 4101.8; 
2006 Emissions per Capita: 7.6. 

Russia: 
1995 Emissions: 1582.9; 
2006 Emissions: 1587.2; 
2006 Emissions per Capita: 11.14. 

India: 
1995 Emissions: 782.6; 
2006 Emissions: 1249.7; 
2006 Emissions per Capita: 1.13. 

Canada: 
1995 Emissions: 465.1; 
2006 Emissions: 538.8; 
2006 Emissions per Capita: 16.52. 

Korea: 
1995 Emissions: 364.8; 
2006 Emissions: 476.1; 
2006 Emissions per Capita: 9.86; 

Mexico: 
1995 Emissions: 309.6; 
2006 Emissions: 416.3; 
2006 Emissions per Capita: 3.97. 

Brazil: 
1995 Emissions: 238.4; 
2006 Emissions: 332.4; 
2006 Emissions per Capita: 1.76. 

Source: International Energy Agency data on carbon emissions from fuel 
consumption. 	 

[End of figure] 

[End of section] 

Background: International Negotiations And Emissions Pricing: 

Greenhouse gas emissions reductions in all major countries will be 
required to stabilize greenhouse gas concentrations at a level that 
would prevent dangerous climate change. In 1992, 192 countries, 
including the United States, joined the United Nations Framework 
Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), an international treaty to 
consider what may be done to reduce and adapt to global warming. In 
1998, the United States signed the Kyoto Protocol, an international 
agreement to specifically limit greenhouse gas emissions. The United 
States is not bound by the protocol's terms because it was not ratified 
by the Senate. Both the UNFCCC and the Kyoto protocol operate under the 
principal of "common but differentiated responsibilities" to reflect 
the agreement that each nation must contribute to addressing climate 
change, but that the magnitude of its efforts should differ according 
to national circumstances. For example, under the protocol, only Annex 
I countries have quantified emission reduction obligations. To 
negotiate the next round of international commitments, parties to the 
UNFCCC agreed to the "Bali Action Plan" in December 2007. 

Countries can take varying approaches to reducing greenhouse gas 
emissions. Since energy use is a significant source of greenhouse gas 
emissions, policies designed to increase energy efficiency or induce a 
switch to less greenhouse gas-intensive fuels, such as from coal to 
natural gas, can reduce emissions in the short term. In the long term, 
however, major technology changes will be needed to establish a less 
carbon-intensive energy infrastructure. To that end, a U.S. policy to 
mitigate climate change may require facilities to achieve specified 
reductions or employ a market-based mechanism, such as establishing a 
price on emissions. 

Proposed Legislation Includes Two Options for Domestic Emissions 
Pricing Systems: 

Through greenhouse gas emissions pricing, governments create an 
incentive for parties to lower their greenhouse gas emissions by 
placing a cost on the emissions. Proposed U.S. legislation includes two 
basic approaches to greenhouse gas emissions pricing: a carbon tax 
system and a cap-and-trade system. A carbon tax system would impose a 
fee on emissions of greenhouse gases. Under a cap-and-trade system, the 
government would cap greenhouse gas emissions, limiting the total 
quantity of emissions from regulated sources under the system. The 
government would also issue allowances, or permits to emit greenhouse 
gases, equal to the overall cap or quota. Regulated sources would be 
required to hold enough allowances to cover their emissions, and 
allowances could be bought and sold as needed to meet the system's 
requirements in the least expensive manner. 

Several bills to implement emissions pricing in the United States have 
been introduced in the 110th and the 111th Congresses. These bills have 
included both cap-and-trade and carbon tax proposals. Some of the 
proposed legislation also include measures intended to limit 
potentially adverse impacts on the international competitiveness of 
domestic firms. 

The Kyoto Protocol: 

The Kyoto Protocol, adopted in Kyoto, Japan, and ratified by more than 
180 countries, sets legally binding emissions targets for 37 
industrialized countries and the European Community (Annex I 
countries). 

The Bali Action Plan: 

The year 2012 will mark the end of the first commitment period of the 
Kyoto Protocol. In Bali, Indonesia, in 2007, countries agreed to the 
Bali Action Plan, which defined a process and timeframe to enable the 
full effective and sustained implementation of the Convention through 
long-term cooperative action up to and beyond 2012. According to the 
Bali Action Plan, the negotiations process is scheduled to conclude in 
December 2009 at a major summit in Copenhagen, Denmark. 

Existing Emissions Pricing Systems: 

Greenhouse gas emissions pricing has been implemented in several other 
cases, including a cap-and-trade system in the European Union (EU) and 
carbon tax systems in Sweden, Finland, Norway, and the Netherlands. The 
world's largest emissions pricing system, the European Union Emissions 
Trading Scheme (EU ETS), covers CO2 emissions from more than 11,000 
energy-intensive installations. The EU ETS began with a pilot phase 
that ran from 2005 to 2007. Its second trading period is currently 
under way. For more information see GAO-09-151. 

[End of section] 

1. Estimating Industry Effects: Introduction: 

In this section, we present information on what is known about how U.S. 
emissions pricing could potentially affect industry competitiveness. 
Importantly, estimating the effects of domestic emissions pricing for 
industries in the United States is complex. For example, if the United 
States were to regulate greenhouse gas emissions, production costs 
could rise for many industries and could cause output, profits, or 
employment to fall. However, the magnitude of these potential effects 
is likely to depend on the greenhouse gas intensity of industry output 
and on the domestic emissions price, which is not yet known, among 
other factors. Additionally, if U.S. climate policy were more stringent 
than in other countries, some domestic industries could experience a 
loss in international competitiveness. Within these industries, adverse 
competitiveness effects could arise through an increase in imports, a 
decrease in exports, or both. 

To estimate the potential economic effects of U.S. emissions pricing on 
domestic industries, models require key assumptions, which cause 
estimates to vary. In this section, we review two economic models that 
specifically estimate competitiveness effects for U.S. industries. In 
each, larger adverse effects occur for those U.S. industries that are 
both relatively energy and trade intensive. We also present information 
on the potential for adverse international competitiveness effects to 
be a source of carbon leakage. 

U.S. emissions pricing effects on production costs and output: 

For regulated sources, greenhouse gas emissions pricing would increase 
the cost of releasing greenhouse gases. As a result, it would encourage 
some of these sources to reduce their emissions, compared with business-
as-usual. Under domestic emissions pricing, production costs for 
regulated sources could rise as they either take action to reduce their 
emissions or pay for the greenhouse gases they release. Cost increases 
are likely to be larger for production that is relatively greenhouse 
gas intensive, where greenhouse gas intensity refers to emissions per 
unit of output. Cost increases may reduce industry profits, or they may 
be passed on to consumers in the form of higher prices. To the extent 
that cost increases are passed on to consumers, they could demand fewer 
goods, and industry output could fall. 

While emissions pricing would likely cause production costs to rise for 
certain industries, the extent of this rise and the resulting impact on 
industry output are less certain due to a number of factors. For 
example, the U.S. emissions price and the emissions price in other 
countries are key variables that will help to determine the impact of 
emissions pricing on domestic industries. However, future emission 
prices are currently unknown. Furthermore, to the extent that emissions 
pricing encourages technological change that reduces greenhouse gas 
intensity, potential adverse effects of emissions pricing on profits or 
output could be mitigated for U.S. industries. Additionally, policy 
options such as output-based rebates could also offset some of the 
added costs of emissions pricing for some firms but involve tradeoffs, 
such as possibly increasing costs for firms that do not receive them. 

Estimated effects from economic models of emissions pricing: 

Several studies by U.S. agencies and experts have used models of the 
economy to simulate the effects of emissions pricing policy on output 
and related economic outcomes. These models generally find that 
emissions pricing will cause output, profits or employment to decline 
in sectors that are described as energy intensive, compared with 
business-as-usual. In general, these studies conclude that these 
declines are likely to be greater for these industries, as compared to 
other sectors in the economy. However, some research suggests that not 
every industry is likely to suffer adverse effects from emissions 
pricing. For example, a long-run model estimated by Ho, Morgenstern, 
and Shih (2008) predicts that some U.S. sectors, such as services, may 
experience growth in the long run as a result of domestic emissions 
pricing. This growth would likely be due to changes in consumption 
patterns in favor of goods and services that are relatively less 
greenhouse gas intensive. 

Potential international competitiveness effects depend in part on the 
stringency of U.S. climate policy relative to other countries. For 
example, if domestic greenhouse gas emissions pricing were to make 
emissions more expensive in the United States than in other countries, 
production costs for domestic industries would likely increase relative 
to their international competitors, potentially disadvantaging 
industries in the United States. As a result, some domestic production 
could shift abroad, through changes in consumption or investment 
patterns, to countries where greenhouse gas emissions are less 
stringently regulated. For example, consumers may substitute some goods 
made in other countries for some goods made domestically. Similarly, 
investment patterns could shift more strongly in favor of new capacity 
in countries where greenhouse gas emissions are regulated less 
stringently than in the United States. 

Economists such as Aldy and Pizer (2009) have defined adverse 
international competitiveness effects as the part of a decline in 
domestic output that is due to a shift of production abroad in response 
to emissions pricing, or the part of a decline in domestic output that 
not also matched by a decline in domestic consumption. For example, if 
domestic output were to fall by more than domestic consumption, the 
difference could be explained by changes in trade patterns through a 
reduction in exports, an increase in imports, or both. 

Factors that may affect international competitiveness: 

Stakeholders and experts have identified two criteria, among others, 
that are important in determining potential vulnerability to adverse 
competitiveness effects: trade intensity and energy intensity. Trade 
intensity is important because international competitiveness effects 
arise from changes in trade patterns. For example, if climate policy in 
the United States were more stringent than in other countries, 
international competition could limit the ability of domestic firms to 
pass increases in costs through to consumers. Energy intensity is 
important because the combustion of fossil fuels for energy is a 
significant source of greenhouse gas emissions, which may increase 
production costs under emissions pricing. International competitiveness 
effects may also depend on other factors, including transportation 
costs and access to markets for natural resources, capital, or labor. 

Industries that are both relatively trade intensive and energy 
intensive include primary metals, nonmetallic minerals, paper products, 
and chemicals. These four industries provided around 4.5 percent of 
total U.S. output in 2007. 

Legislation passed in June 2009 by the House of Representatives, H.R. 
2454, 111TH Cong. (2009), uses the criteria of trade intensity and 
energy intensity or greenhouse gas intensity, among others, to 
determine eligibility for the Emission Allowance Rebate Program that is 
part of the legislation. H.R. 2454 specifies how to calculate the two 
criteria. Trade intensity is defined as the ratio of the sum of the 
value of imports and exports within an industry to the sum of the value 
of shipments (output) and imports within the industry. Energy intensity 
is defined as the industry's cost of purchased electricity and fuel 
costs, or energy expenditures, divided by the value of shipments 
(output) of the industry. 

The energy intensity measure specified in this legislation, however, 
might not be an ideal measure of vulnerability. First, the relationship 
between energy expenditures and emissions from energy use is 
indeterminate. For example, energy expenditures depend on the price of 
fuel and on the quantity of fuel used, while emissions from energy use 
depend on the quantity and type of fuel used. Additionally, an increase 
in energy prices may cause expenditures on energy to rise and energy 
use to fall, which could also cause emissions from energy use to fall. 
Second, the energy intensity measure might not reflect the extent to 
which substitutes for energy are available. For example, regulated 
sources may be able to reduce their energy intensity or switch to 
energy sources that are less greenhouse gas intensive. To the extent 
that less greenhouse gas intensive substitutes are available, some 
industries could reduce the effect of emissions pricing on their costs 
and on their competitiveness. 

Key assumptions of models that estimate competitiveness effects: 

Key assumptions made by economic models of emissions pricing include, 
among others, the domestic emissions price, the emissions price in 
other countries, the level of industry aggregation, and the time 
horizon during which producers may adjust their production methods or 
energy sources in response to emissions pricing. 

* Domestic emissions price: The domestic emissions price could affect 
the size of a potential increase in production costs from emissions 
pricing. In particular, increases in production costs are expected to 
be larger when the domestic emissions price is greater. Under a carbon 
tax system, the domestic emissions price would equal the tax per unit 
of emissions. Under a cap-and-trade system, the domestic emissions 
price would equal the market-clearing allowance price, at which the 
quantity of allowances supplied equals the quantity of allowances 
demanded. 

The domestic emissions price could also depend on cost containment 
features of an emissions pricing system, such as banking, borrowing or 
carbon offsets, among other features. 

* Emissions price in other countries: Together with the domestic 
emissions price, the emissions price in other countries will help to 
determine the relative stringency of climate policy in the United 
States. When the difference between the domestic emissions price and a 
lower emissions price in other countries is larger, U.S. industries may 
be more likely to experience adverse competitiveness effects from 
domestic emissions pricing. Under a cap-and-trade system, differences 
in the allowance price between two countries may dissipate if 
international trading of allowances is allowed. 

* Level of aggregation: The range of estimated effects may depend on 
the level of industrial or sectoral aggregation used. For example, 
estimates for highly aggregated sectors could mask more extreme 
variation at the more narrowly aggregated sub-industry level. 

* Time horizon: In models of economic activity, the amount of time 
considered after policy implementation may affect model results. For 
example, the time horizon may affect the ability of firms to pass 
through added costs to consumers in the form of higher prices, change 
their production processes, or develop and adopt new technologies. A 
longer time horizon could also allow for investments in new capacity. 

* Policy Scenarios: Model results may depend in part upon the range of 
policy scenarios incorporated. For example the incorporation of trade 
measures and output-based rebates may affect the results. 

Estimates of competitiveness effects are uncertain: 

Table 1 presents results from two studies that attempt to quantify the 
potential competitiveness effects on domestic industries from emissions 
pricing. For each study, a range of estimates is reported for two 
effects: (1) the potential decline in domestic, energy-intensive 
manufacturing output that is due to U.S. emissions pricing and (2) the 
part of this decline that is due to adverse international 
competitiveness effects. The adverse competitiveness effects are 
computed as the difference between the production and consumption 
impacts of emissions pricing. For example, if production declines by 
3.7 percent and consumption declines by 2.9 percent as a share of 
production, the adverse competitiveness effect equals the -0.8 percent 
change in production that is not matched by a change in domestic 
consumption. 

In both studies, estimates of competitiveness effects are generally 
greater for industries that are relatively trade and energy intensive. 

The estimated impacts depend on key assumptions of the models used to 
generate these results. Both studies assume unilateral action by the 
United States, or an emissions price of $0 per ton of carbon dioxide in 
the rest of the world, which may overstate the estimates of adverse 
competitiveness effects for U.S. industries to the extent that other 
countries also regulate greenhouse gas emissions. 

Aldy and Pizer's (2009) model allows for some adjustments and is 
consistent with a time horizon of 1 year to a few years. Ho et al. 
(2008) generate their long-run estimates using a model that allows for 
more adjustments. 

Table 1: Estimates of Emissions Pricing Effects on Energy-Intensive 
Manufacturing Industries in the United States: 

Estimated decline in industry output due to emissions pricing (range of 
estimates): 
Study: Aldy and Pizer (2009): 1.0% - 4.3%; 
Study: Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008): 0.91% - 1.30%. 

Part of estimated decline in industry output due to adverse 
international competitiveness effects (range of estimates): 
Study: Aldy and Pizer (2009): 0.3% - 1.8%; 
Study: Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008): 0.42% - 0.68%. 

Domestic emissions price (per ton of carbon dioxide): 
Study: Aldy and Pizer (2009): $15; 
Study: Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008): $10. 

Emissions price in other countries (per ton of carbon dioxide): 
Study: Aldy and Pizer (2009): $0; 
Study: Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008): $0. 

Time horizon: 
Study: Aldy and Pizer (2009): 1 year to a few years; 
Study: Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008): Long run. 

Number of industries in model: 
Study: Aldy and Pizer (2009): 400+; 
Study: Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008): 21. 

Number of industries for which results are reported by authors: 
Study: Aldy and Pizer (2009): 55 energy-intensive; 
Study: Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008): 21. 

Number of industries included in the ranges of estimates reported 
above: 
Study: Aldy and Pizer (2009): 55; 
Study: Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008): 3 most energy-intensive. 

Incorporation of trade measure and output-based rebate policies: 
Study: Aldy and Pizer (2009): no; 
Study: Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008): no. 

Source: GAO analysis of results reported by Aldy and Pizer (2009) and 
Ho, Morgenstern, and Shih (2008). Note: The number of industries in 
both reflects, in part, the level of industry aggregation. While Aldy 
and Pizer (2009) examine more than 400 industries at a more narrowly 
aggregated level, they report estimates only for 55 energy-intensive 
industries among the more than 400 industries they examine. Ho et al. 
(2008) examine industries at a more aggregated level and report 
estimates for all 21 manufacturing and nonmanufacturing sectors that 
they consider. Ho et al. (2008) also report estimates of the effects of 
emissions pricing on industry output for multiple time horizons, but 
they report both production and consumption effects--both of which are 
necessary to compute competitiveness effects--only for their long run 
estimates. For the study by Aldy and Pizer (2009), the estimated 
decline in industry output and the part that is due to competitiveness 
effects are reported as a percentage of industry output. For the study 
by Ho et al. (2008), the estimated decline in industry output and the 
part that is due to competitiveness effects are reported as a share of 
sectoral consumption. 

[End of table] 

International competitiveness effects and carbon leakage: 

Reducing carbon emissions in the United States could result in carbon 
leakage through two potential mechanisms. First, if domestic production 
were to shift abroad to countries where greenhouse gas emissions are 
not regulated, emissions in these countries could grow faster than 
expected otherwise. Through this mechanism, some of the expected 
benefits of reducing emissions domestically could be offset by faster 
growth in emissions elsewhere, according to Aldy and Pizer (2009). 

Carbon leakage may also arise from changes in world prices that are 
brought about by domestic emissions pricing. For example, U.S. 
emissions pricing could cause domestic demand for oil to fall. Because 
the United States is a relatively large consumer of oil worldwide, the 
world price of oil could fall when the U.S. demand for oil drops. The 
quantity of oil consumed by other countries would rise in response, 
increasing greenhouse gas emissions from the rest of the world. These 
price effects may be a more important source of carbon leakage than the 
trade effects described above. See Fischer and Fox (2009) and EPA 
(2009). 

[End of section] 

2. Potentially Vulnerable Industries: Introduction: 

In this section, we provide some information on certain U.S. industries 
that, by paying a price on greenhouse gas emissions, could potentially 
lose competitiveness compared with foreign industries without 
comparable climate policies. Among many factors, two key indicators of 
potential vulnerability to adverse competitiveness effects are an 
industry's energy intensity and trade intensity. Proposed U.S. 
legislation specifies that: (a) either an energy intensity or 
greenhouse gas intensity of 5 percent or greater; and (b) a trade 
intensity of 15 percent or greater be used as criteria to identify 
industries for which trade measures or rebates would apply. Since data 
on greenhouse gas intensity is less complete, we focus our analysis on 
industry energy intensity. Most of the industries that meet these 
criteria are in primary metals, nonmetallic minerals, paper, and 
chemicals, yet there is significant variation in specified 
vulnerability characteristics among different product groups ("sub- 
industries"). The following pages include examples of this variation, 
as well as information on the type of energy used and location of 
import and export markets. Data shown are for the latest year 
available, with additional discussion of proposed vulnerability 
criteria in appendix I and industry information in appendix II. 

Energy and trade intensities of the four manufacturing industries, in 
the aggregate, generally meet both vulnerability criteria in proposed 
legislation. As shown along the right axis in figure 2, nonmetallic 
minerals is the most energy intensive at 6.1 percent in 2006. As shown 
along the left axis, chemicals is the most trade intensive, at 45 
percent in 2007. While chemicals does not have an energy intensity of 5 
percent or greater--and is located outside of the shaded area--several 
sub-industries within chemicals meet that vulnerability criterion. 

Together, these four industries provided 23 percent of total U.S. 
manufacturing output in 2007 and had trade flows of about $500 billion. 
As shown by the size of the column, chemicals is the largest industry, 
with output of $664 billion in 2007. Accordingly, chemicals also 
accounted for the largest share of carbon dioxide emissions from 
manufacturing, at 22 percent in 2002. However, the estimated greenhouse 
gas intensity of chemical products--the level of carbon dioxide emitted 
per unit of energy--was less than that for both primary metals and 
nonmetallic minerals in 2002. 

Figure 2: Energy and Trade Intensity Are Indicators of Vulnerability: 

[Refer to PDF for image: 3-D bar graph] 

Primary Metals: 
Value of output: $241 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 5.2; 
Trade Intensity: 40.4%. 

Non-Metallic Minerals: 
Value of output: $119 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 6.1%; 
Trade Intensity: 20.4%. 

Paper: 
Value of output: $168 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 5.5%; 
Trade Intensity: 22.5%. 

Chemicals: 
Value of output: $664 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 3.6%; 
Trade Intensity: 45.4%. 

Criteria for industry vulnerability: 
Over 5% energy intensity and over 15% trade intensity. 

Source: GAO analysis of Department of Energy emissions data and 
Department of Commerce energy data for 2006 and trade and output data 
for 2007.							 

[End of figure] 

2.1. Potentially Vulnerable Industries: Primary Metals Examples: 

As shown by sub-industry examples in figure 3, energy and trade 
intensities differ within primary metals. For example, primary aluminum 
meets the vulnerability criteria with an energy intensity of 24 percent 
and trade intensity of 62 percent. Ferrous metal foundries meets the 
energy intensity criteria, but not the trade intensity criteria. Steel 
manufacturing--products made from purchased steel--and aluminum 
products fall short of both vulnerability criteria. Iron and steel 
mills has an energy intensity of 7 percent and a trade intensity of 35 
percent and is by far the largest sub-industry example, with a 2007 
value of output of over $93 billion. 

Figure 3: Energy and Trade Intensity Indicators Vary by Sub-Industry: 

[Refer to PDF for image: 3-D bar graph] 

Iron and steel mills: 
Value of output: $93.2 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 6.7%. 
Trade Intensity: 34.7%. 

Electrometallurgical products: 
Value of output: $1.7 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 6.7%. 
Trade Intensity: 71.0%. 

Steel manufacturing: 
Value of output: $19.9 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 2.6%. 
Trade Intensity: 10.1%. 

Ferrous metal foundries: 
Value of output: $20.1 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 5.7%. 
Trade Intensity: 9.1%. 

Primary aluminum: 
Value of output: $6.7 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 23.6%. 
Trade Intensity: 62.0%. 

Aluminum products: 
Value of output: $16.7 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 4.2%. 
Trade Intensity: 11.2%. 

Criteria for industry vulnerability: 
Over 5% energy intensity and over 15% trade intensity. 

Source: GAO analysis of Department of Commerce energy data for 2006 and 
trade data for 2007. 

[End of figure] 			 

Among the primary metals sub-industry examples, types of energy used 
also vary. Iron and steel mills use the greatest share of coal and 
coke, and steel manufacturing and ferrous metal foundries use the 
greatest proportion of natural gas. Since coal is more carbon intensive 
than natural gas, sub-industries that rely more heavily on coal could 
also be more vulnerable to competitiveness effects. The carbon 
intensity of electricity, used heavily in the production of aluminum, 
will also vary on the basis of source of energy used to generate it and 
the market conditions where it is sold. Data shown for "aluminum" 
include primary aluminum and aluminum products and net electricity is 
the sum of net transfers plus purchases and generation minus quantities 
sold. 

Figure 4: Type of Energy Used Is Important for Carbon Intensity (share 
of total 2002 energy consumed as a percentage of BTUs): 

[Refer to PDF for image: stacked vertical bar graph] 

Iron and steel mills: 
Coal and Coke: 56.3%; 
Natural Gas: 28.7%; 
Renewables and Other: 2.3%; 
Net Electricity: 12.7%. 

Electrometallurgical products: 
Coal and Coke: 18.5%; 
Natural Gas: 25.9%; 
Renewables and Other: 11.1%; 
Net Electricity: 44.4%. 

Steel manufacturing: 
Coal and Coke: 0.0%; 
Natural Gas: 53.3%; 
Renewables and Other: 11.1%; 
Net Electricity: 35.6%. 

Ferrous metal foundries: 
Coal and Coke: 18.2%; 
Natural Gas: 46.7%; 
Renewables and Other: 2.4%; 
Net Electricity: 32.7%. 

Aluminum products: 
Coal and Coke: 0.0%; 
Natural Gas: 28.5%; 
Renewables and Other: 30.7%; 
Net Electricity: 40.8%. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the Department of Energy. 

[End of figure] 

Industry vulnerability may further vary depending on the share of trade 
with countries that do not have carbon pricing. To illustrate this 
variability, figure 5 provides data on the share of imports by source, 
since imports exceed exports in each of the primary metals examples. As 
shown, while primary aluminum is among the most trade intensive, the 
majority of imports are from Canada, an Annex I country with agreed 
emission reduction targets. For iron and steel mills, over one-third of 
imports are from the EU and other Annex I countries, not including 
Canada ("EU plus"). However, for iron and steel mills, almost 30 
percent of imports are also from the non-Annex I countries of China, 
Mexico, and Brazil. While less trade intensive, steel manufacturing and 
aluminum products each has greater than one-third of imports from China 
alone. 

Figure 5: Source of Imports Is Important for Trade Intensity: 

[Refer to PDF for image: stacked vertical bar graph] 

Share of 2007 total imports (percentage): 

Iron and steel mills: 
EU Plus: 34.8%	
Canada: 17.1%	
China: 13.1%	
Mexico: 7.5%	
Brazil: 8.3%
Other: 19.2%. 

Electrometallurgical products: 
EU Plus: 8.9%; 
Canada: 3.2%; 
China: 11.3%; 
Mexico: 0.9%; 
Brazil: 5.5%; 
Other: 70.2%. 

Steel manufacturing: 
EU Plus: 19.3%; 
Canada: 13.7%; 
China: 36.9%; 
Mexico: 7.3%; 
Brazil: 0.7%; 
Other: 22.1%. 

Ferrous metal foundries: 
EU Plus: 23.0%; 
Canada: 13.3%; 
China: 31.5%; 
Mexico: 5.0%; 
Brazil: 5.3%; 
Other: 24.9%. 

Primary aluminum: 
EU Plus: 4.1%; 
Canada: 65.1%; 
China: 1.3%; 
Mexico: 1.3%; 
Brazil: 2.7%; 
Other: 25.5%. 

Aluminum products: 
EU Plus: 17.1%; 
Canada: 32.6%; 
China: 33.9%; 
Mexico: 3.3%; 
Brazil: 0.6%; 
Other: 12.5%. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the International Trade 
Administration. 

[End of table] 

Adverse competitiveness effects from emissions pricing could increase 
the already growing share of Chinese imports that exists in some of the 
sub-industries. Among the examples, iron and steel mills, steel 
manufacturing, and aluminum products exhibit a growing trade reliance 
on Chinese imports since 2002. This trend has largely been driven by 
lower labor and capital costs in China and, according to 
representatives from the steel industry, China has recently been 
producing 50 percent of the world's steel. 

Figure 6: Sub-Industries With Growing Share of Imports from China: 

[Refer to PDF for image: multiple line graph] 

Year: 2002; 
Iron and steel mills: 2.7%; 
Steel manufacturing: 11.4%; 
Aluminum products: 6.1%. 

Year: 2003; 
Iron and steel mills: 3%; 
Steel manufacturing: 15.6%; 
Aluminum products: 9.6%. 

Year: 2004; 
Iron and steel mills: 7.3%; 
Steel manufacturing: 20.1%; 
Aluminum products: 17.6%. 

Year: 2005; 
Iron and steel mills: 7.8%; 
Steel manufacturing: 27.6%; 
Aluminum products: 26.3%. 

Year: 2006; 
Iron and steel mills: 11.7%; 
Steel manufacturing: 33.7%; 
Aluminum products: 34.2%. 

Year: 2007; 
Iron and steel mills: 13.1%; 
Steel manufacturing: 36.9%; 
Aluminum products: 33.9%. 

Total U.S. imports by value (U.S. dollars in millions): 

Iron and steel mills: 
2002: $12,558; 
2003: $10,808; 
2004: $23,355; 
2005: $25,131; 
2006: $33,060; 
2007: $30,445. 

Steel manufacturing 
2002: $1,110; 
2003: $1,184; 
2004: $1,792; 
2005: $1,884; 
2006: $1,916; 
2007: $1,822. 

Aluminum products 
2002: $498; 
2003: $549; 
2004: $718; 
2005: $913; 
2006: $1,209; 
2007: $1,183. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the Department of Commerce. 

[End of figure] 

2.2. Potentially Vulnerable Industries: Nonmetallic Minerals Examples: 

Among nonmetallic minerals sub-industry examples, cement has the 
highest energy intensity, at 16 percent, and glass and clay building 
materials have the highest trade intensity, at 36 percent and 35 
percent, respectively. While, concrete is the largest sub-industry, 
with a value of output of over $30 billion in 2007, it fails to meet 
both of the vulnerability criteria and thus lies outside of the shaded 
floor area. Lime and gypsum meets the energy intensity criteria but 
fails to meet the trade intensity criteria. 

Figure 7: Energy and Trade Intensity Indicators Vary by Sub-Industry: 

[Refer to PDF for image: 3-D bar graph] 
	
Cement: 
Value of output: $10.2 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 15.6%; 
Trade Intensity: 12.4%. 	 

Concrete	
Value of output: $30.1 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 1.7%; 
Trade Intensity: 0.0%. 	 

Lime and Gypsum	
Value of output: $8.6 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 12.3%; 
Trade Intensity: 4.1%. 	 

Glass	
Value of output: $22.4 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 8.7%; 
Trade Intensity: 36.0%. 	 

Clay Building Material	
Value of output: $3.3 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 13.6%; 
Trade Intensity: 35.3%. 

Mineral Wool	
Value of output: $6.0 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 8.7%; 
Trade Intensity: 18.1%. 

Criteria for industry vulnerability: 
Over 5% energy intensity and over 15% trade intensity. 
	
Source: GAO analysis of Department of Commerce energy data for 2006 and 
trade data for 2007. 

[End of figure] 

Cement and lime rely on coal and coke sources for about 60 percent of 
energy consumed, while glass and mineral wool rely on natural gas for 
over 65 percent of energy consumed. Since coal is more carbon intensive 
than natural gas, sub-industries that rely more heavily on coal could 
also be more vulnerable to competitiveness effects. Data on energy use 
by the sub-industry examples excluded from the chart are not currently 
reported by the Department of Energy. 

Figure 8: Type of Energy Used Is Important for Carbon Intensity: 

[Refer to PDF for image: stacked vertical bar graph] 

Share of 2002 total energy consumed (percentage of BTUs): 

Cement: 
Coal and Coke: 59.7%; 
Natural Gas: 5.1%; 
Renewables and Other: 24.7%; 
Net Electricity: 10.5%. 

Lime: 
Coal and Coke: 62.3%; 
Natural Gas: 7.5%; 
Renewables and Other: 25.5%; 
Net Electricity: 4.7%. 

Glass: 
Coal and Coke: 0.0%; 
Natural Gas: 76.1%; 
Renewables and Other: 3.0%; 
Net Electricity: 20.9%. 

Mineral Wool: 
Coal and Coke: 5.8%; 
Natural Gas: 67.3%; 
Renewables and Other: 1.9%; 
Net Electricity: 25.0%. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the Department of Energy. 

[End of figure] 

For the nonmetallic mineral examples, total imports exceed total 
exports. As shown in figure 9, glass has the largest share of imports 
from China, at 26 percent. Another 17 percent of glass imports are 
sourced from Mexico. For the other trade-intensive sub-industries of 
cement, clay building material, and mineral wool, about 30 percent of 
imports are from China, Mexico, and Brazil. Conversely, nearly 60 
percent of lime and gypsum imports are from Canada. 

The one sub-industry where exports comprise more than 60 percent of 
trade flows is concrete, with 30 percent of concrete exports sold to 
markets in Mexico and the Middle East. 

Figure 9: Source of Imports Is Important for Trade Intensity: 

[Refer to PDF for image: stacked vertical bar graph] 

Share of 2007 total U.S. imports: 

Cement: 
EU Plus: 10.5%; 
Canada: 29.2%; 
China: 18.5%; 
Mexico: 8.7%; 
Brazil: 2.9%; 
Other: 30.2%. 

Concrete: 
EU Plus: 20.6%; 
Canada: 79.4%; 
China: 0.0%; 
Mexico: 0.0%; 
Brazil: 0.0%; 
Other: 0.0%. 

Lime and Gypsum: 
EU Plus: 3.3%; 
Canada: 59.9%; 
China: 3.6%; 
Mexico: 32.5%; 
Brazil: 0.0%; 
Other: 0.7%. 

Glass: 
EU Plus: 36.7%; 
Canada: 11.8%; 
China: 26.3%; 
Mexico: 16.8%; 
Brazil: 0.5%; 
Other: 7.9%. 

Clay Building Material: 
EU Plus: 60.2%; 
Canada: 0.5%; 
China: 8.9%; 
Mexico: 14.9%; 
Brazil: 8.0%; 
Other: 7.5%. 

Mineral Wool: 
EU Plus: 26.6%; 
Canada: 41.2%; 
China: 9.8%; 
Mexico: 18.6%; 
Brazil: 0.2%
Other: 3.6%. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the International Trade 
Administration. 

[End of figure] 

Since 2002, a trend of increasing Chinese imports as a share of total 
imports is evident for glass and mineral wool. While the share of 
cement imports from China declined from 2006 to 2007, reliance on 
Chinese imports has also grown relative to 2002. According to 
representatives of the U.S. cement industry, Chinese production costs 
are between 20 percent and 40 percent of those in the United States. 

Figure 10: Sub-Industries With Growing Share of Imports from China: 

[Refer to PDF for image: multiple line graph] 

Chinese imports as a share of total imports (percentage): 

Cement: 
2002: 7.1%; 
2003: 7.1%; 
2004: 6.4%; 
2005: 12.9%; 
2006: 25.7%; 
2007: 18.5%. 

Glass: 
2002: 18.2%; 
2003: 18.9%; 
2004: 19.9%; 
2005: 22.5%; 
2006: 24.4%; 
2007: 26.3%; 

Mineral Wool: 
2002: 2.1%; 
2003: 3.2%; 
2004: 3.7%; 
2005: 7.9%; 
2006: 8.7%; 
2007: 9.8%. 

Total imports by value ($US dollars in millions): 

Cement: 
2002: $938; 
2003: $924; 
2004: $1,140; 
2005: $1,567; 
2006: $1,837; 
2007: $1,325. 

Glass: 
2002: $4,293; 
2003: $4,436; 
2004: $4,947; 
2005: $5,125; 
2006: $5,491; 
2007: $5,726. 

Mineral Wool: 
2002: $332; 
2003: $360; 
2004: $448; 
2005: $510; 
2006: $577; 
2007: $489. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the International Trade 
Administration.	 

[End of figure] 

2.3. Potentially Vulnerable Industries: Paper Products Examples: 

Sub-industry examples within paper products also show variation in 
energy and trade intensity. Pulp mills is the most trade intensive, at 
98 percent. Paper mills is the largest sub-industry, with a 2007 value 
of output of over $51 billion and its trade intensity is 30 percent. 
Pulp mills and paper mills each has an energy intensity of 8 percent 
and, thus, meet both vulnerability criteria. While paperboard mills has 
an energy intensity of 12 percent, it does not meet the trade intensity 
criteria. Paperboard containers fails to meet both criteria but was the 
second largest sub-industry in 2007, with a value of output of over $47 
billion. 

Figure 11: Energy and Trade Intensity Indicators Vary by Sub-Industry: 

[Refer to PDF for image: 3-D bar graph] 

Pulp Mills: 
Value of output: $4.3 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 8.4%; 
Trade Intensity: 98.2%. 

Paper Mills: 
Value of output: $51.4 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 8.4%; 
Trade Intensity: 30.1%. 

Paperboard Mills: 
Value of output: $23.2 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 12.3%; 
Trade Intensity: 0.9%. 

Paperboard Containers: 
Value of output: $47.7 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 1.8%; 
Trade Intensity: 6.4%. 

Criteria for industry vulnerability: 
Over 5% energy intensity and over 15% trade intensity. 
	
Source: GAO analysis of Department of Commerce energy data for 2006 and 
trade data for 2007. 

[End of figure] 

In paper mills and paperboard mills, the largest share of energy 
consumed is from the relatively less carbon-intensive renewable and 
other (such as fuel oil and steam) energy sources. An additional 20 
percent of energy consumed is from natural gas, while coal and coke 
sources provide 14 percent of energy for paper mills and 9 percent of 
energy for paperboard mills. While energy use data for pulp mills is 
reported by the Department of Energy, consumption of coal and coke, 
specifically, is not publicly available, so percentage shares could not 
be computed. Data on energy use by paperboard containers are not 
currently reported. 

Figure 12: Type of Energy Used Is Important for Carbon Intensity: 

[Refer to PDF for image: stacked vertical bar graph] 

Share of 2002 total energy consumed (percentage of BTUs): 

Paper Mills: 
Coal and coke: 14.3%; 
Natural gas: 20.6%; 
Renewable and other: 57.4%; 
Net electricity: 7.8%. 

Paperboard Mills: 
Coal and coke: 9.3%; 
Natural gas: 20.7%; 
Renewable and other: 63.9%; 
Net electricity: 6.2%. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the Department of Energy. 

[End of figure] 

For the paper products sub-industry examples, total imports exceed 
total exports. For each, the largest share of imports is from Canada, 
an Annex I country with agreed emission reduction targets. However, for 
the most trade-intensive example of pulp mills, 19 percent of imports 
are from Brazil. While paperboard containers has a trade intensity of 
only 6 percent, 27 percent of imports are from China. 

Figure 13: Source of Imports Is Important for Trade Intensity: 

[Refer to PDF for image: stacked vertical bar graph] 

Share of 2007 total U.S. imports: 

Pulp Mills: 
EU Plus: 4.2%; 
Canada: 74.1%; 
China: 0.3%; 
Mexico: 0.1%; 
Brazil: 18.6%; 
Other: 1.7%. 

Paper Mills: 
EU Plus: 27.3%; 
Canada: 62.1%; 
China: 3.9%; 
Mexico: 1.2%; 
Brazil: 0.5%; 
Other: 5.0%. 

Paperboard Mills: 
EU Plus: 5.7%; 
Canada: 93.3%; 
China: 0.9%; 
Mexico: 0.0%; 
Brazil: 0.0%; 
Other: 0.1%. 

Paperboard Containers: 
EU Plus: 9.1%; 
Canada: 49.7%; 
China: 27.3%; 
Mexico: 4.4%; 
Brazil: 0.1%; 
Other: 9.1%. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the International Trade 
Administration. 

[End of figure] 

Among the paper products sub-industries, paperboard containers is the 
only example with a significant share of imports from China. While 
paperboard containers fails to meet the trade-intensity vulnerability 
criteria, emissions pricing could magnify the growing share of imports 
from China for that sub-industry. From 2002 to 2007, this share has 
grown from 11 percent to 27 percent of U.S. imports. 

Figure 14: Sub-Industries With Growing Share of Imports from China: 

[Refer to PDF for image: line graph] 

Chinese imports as a share of total U.S. imports: 

Paperboard Containers: 
2002: 11.0%; 
2003: 14.3%; 
2004: 16.3%; 
2005: 19.1%; 
2006: 22.0%; 
2007: 27.3%. 

Total imports by value ($US dollars in millions): 

Paperboard Containers: 
2002: $790; 
2003: $875; 
2004: $926; 
2005: $1,033; 
2006: $1,187; 
2007: $1,275. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the International Trade 
Administration.	 

[End of figure] 

2.4. Potentially Vulnerable Industries: Chemicals Examples: 

Among chemicals examples, alkalies and chlorine is the most energy 
intensive, at 26 percent, and nitrogenous fertilizers is the most trade 
intensive, at 82 percent. Except for industrial gases, each of the 
examples meets the energy and trade intensity criteria for 
vulnerability. Industrial gases, the largest sub-industry example, with 
a 2007 value of output of almost $9 billion, has an energy intensity of 
15 percent but a trade intensity of only 5 percent. Not shown in figure 
15 is petrochemicals, with a 2007 value of output of almost $62 
billion. The Department of Commerce does not publicly provide energy- 
intensity data for petrochemicals, though industry experts estimate it 
to be at above 5 percent but below 20 percent. The year 2007 trade data 
indicate a petrochemicals trade intensity of below 15 percent. 

Figure 15: Energy and Trade Intensity Indicators Vary by Sub-Industry: 

[Refer to PDF for image: 3-D bar graph] 

Alkalies and Chlorine: 
Value of output: $6.5 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 26.2%; 
Trade Intensity: 28.1%. 

Carbon Black: 
Value of output: $1.5 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 7.6%; 
Trade Intensity: 24.4%. 

Nitrogenous Fertilizers; 
Value of output: $5.4 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 14.4%; 
Trade Intensity: 81.5%. 

Industrial Gases: 
Value of output: $8.8 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 14.5%; 
Trade Intensity: 5.4%. 

Artificial and Synthetic Fibers: 
Value of output: $8.6 billion; 
Energy Intensity: 6.3%; 
Trade Intensity: 42.2%. 

Criteria for industry vulnerability: 
Over 5% energy intensity and over 15% trade intensity. 

Source: GAO analysis of Department of Commerce energy data for 2006 and 
trade and output data for 2007. 

[End of figure] 

Carbon black relies mostly on renewable and other sources of energy 
that are relatively less carbon intensive than coal. Nearly all of the 
energy consumed by nitrogenous fertilizers is from natural gas. In 
chemical sub-industries, a portion of the carbon contained in the 
energy source is also sequestered in the product rather than emitted to 
the atmosphere. Data on certain energy uses by type for sub-industries 
not shown in figure 16 is not publicly available and percentage shares 
could not be computed. 

Figure 16: Type of Energy Used Is Important for Carbon Intensity: 

[Refer to PDF for image: stacked vertical bar graph] 

Share of 2002 total energy consumed (percentage of BTUs): 

Carbon Black: 
Coal and Coke: 0.0%; 
Natural Gas: 22.7%; 
Renewables and Other: 75.0%; 
Net Electricity: 2.3%. 

Nitrogenous Fertilizers: 
Coal and Coke: 0.0%; 
Natural Gas: 97.4%; 
Renewables and Other: 0.2%; 
Net Electricity: 2.4%. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the Department of Energy. 

[End of figure] 

For the chemicals examples, total imports exceed total exports. 
Nitrogenous fertilizers is the most trade intensive, and less than 40 
percent of imports are from Annex I countries--Canada and EU Plus-- 
while 40 percent of imports are from either Trinidad and Tobago or 
countries in the Middle East. Conversely, imports from Canada provide 
60 percent of imports for carbon black. Imports from China, Mexico, and 
Korea account for 20 percent or more of imports in industrial gases and 
artificial and synthetic fibers. 

Alkalies and chlorine is the only sub-industry example where exports 
comprise more than 60 percent of trade flows, with 15 percent to 
Brazil, 13 percent to Canada, and 12 percent to Mexico. 

Figure 17: Source of Imports Is Important for Trade Intensity: 

[Refer to PDF for image: stacked vertical bar graph] 

Share of 2007 total U.S. imports: 

Alkalies and Chlorine: 
EU Plus: 29.7%; 
Canada: 40.8%; 
China: 7.5%; 
Mexico: 4.5%; 
Korea: 7.6%; 
Other: 9.1%. 

Carbon Black: 
EU Plus: 23.8%; 
Canada: 59.6%; 
China: 0.8%; 
Mexico: 7.1%; 
Korea: 0.3%; 
Other: 8.4%. 

Nitrogenous Fertilizers: 
EU Plus: 13.2%; 
Canada: 23.8%; 
China: 3.5%; 
Mexico: 0.3%; 
Korea: 0.0%; 
Other: 59.8%. 

Industrial Gases: 
EU Plus: 33.1%; 
Canada: 33.2%; 
China: 16.4%; 
Mexico: 6.6%; 
Korea: 0.0%; 
Other: 10.7%. 

Artificial and Synthetic Fibers: 
EU Plus: 35.1%; 
Canada: 15.8%; 
China: 10.3%; 
Mexico: 8.7%; 
Korea: 12.2%; 
Other: 17.9%. 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the International Trade 
Administration. 

[End of figure] 

From 2002 to 2007, the share of imports from China has grown for 
alkalies and chlorine, industrial gases, and artificial and synthetic 
fibers from a share of less than 2 percent to a share of between 8 
percent and 16 percent. According to representatives from the chemical 
industry, growing imports from China are also evident for industry 
downstream products, such as plastics. 

Figure 18: Sub-Industries With Growing Share of Imports from China: 

[Refer to PDF for image: line graph] 

Chinese imports as a share of total U.S. imports: 

Alkalies and Chlorine: 
2002: 0.7%; 
2003: 1.0%; 
2004: 1.2%; 
2005: 2.4%; 
2006: 10.1%; 
2007: 7.5%. 

Industrial Gases: 
2002: 1.8%; 
2003: 4.2%; 
2004: 5.7%; 
2005: 9.4%; 
2006: 8.3%; 
2007: 16.4%. 

Artificial and Synthetic Fibers: 
2002: 1.9%; 
2003: 2.7%; 
2004: 3.4%; 
2005: 7.8%; 
2006: 10.2%; 
2007: 10.3%. 

Total imports by value ($US dollars in millions): 

Alkalies and Chlorine: 
2002: $160; 
2003: $207; 
2004: $253; 
2005: $454; 
2006: $460; 
2007: $400. 

Industrial Gases: 
2002: $125; 
2003: $128; 
2004: $148; 
2005: $160; 
2006: $160; 
2007: $176; 

Artificial and Synthetic Fibers: 
2002: $1,626; 
2003: $1,644; 
2004: $1,814; 
2005: $2,230; 
2006: $2,322; 
2007: $2,471; 

Source: GAO analysis of data from the International Trade 
Administration. 

[End of figure] 

2.5. Potentially Vulnerable Industries: Summary of Industry Examples: 

This section provides data on energy and trade characteristics for sub- 
industries within primary metals, nonmetallic minerals, paper, and 
chemicals. As shown by the data, characteristics that contribute to an 
industry's or sub-industry's potential vulnerability to adverse 
competitiveness effects vary significantly among the examples provided. 
Additional variation would likely exist for factors not discussed, such 
as transportation costs and access to markets for natural resources, 
capital, and labor. As a result, the data provided are not sufficient 
to determine if one sub-industry is more vulnerable than another. 
Instead, the data suggest that an assessment of vulnerability that is 
based only on a sub-industry's energy and trade intensity may mask 
important differences in vulnerability among industries assessed. 

* Primary metals examples: Primary aluminum is the most energy and 
trade intensive, yet the largest share of imports is from Canada. Iron 
and steel is the largest sub-industry that is both energy and trade 
intensive and also has the greatest reliance on coal and coke energy 
sources. Steel manufacturing and aluminum products fall short of 
meeting the trade-intensity criteria, but compared with the other 
examples, have the largest share of imports from China and the most 
pronounced trend of an increased import share from China since 2002. 

* Nonmetallic mineral examples: Cement is the most energy intensive and 
has a relatively greater reliance on coal and coke energies. Glass is 
the most trade intensive and has the largest share of imports from 
China. Both cement and glass show an increasing share of Chinese 
imports since 2002. Concrete, while not meeting the trade-intensity 
criteria, exports more than it imports, with almost one-third of 
exports destined for markets in Mexico and the Middle East. 

* Paper examples: Paper mills is the largest sub-industry example, 
although most imports are from Annex I countries. Almost one-fifth of 
pulp mill imports is from Brazil, although pulp mills is the smallest 
example that meets both energy and trade intensity criteria. Paperboard 
containers do not meet either vulnerability criteria, but show an 
increasing share of imports from China since 2002. 

* Chemicals examples: Nitrogenous fertilizers is the most trade 
intensive, and 40 percent of imports are from Trinidad and Tobago or 
countries in the Middle East. Alkalies and chlorine are the most energy 
intensive and exports account for 79 percent of trade flows, of which, 
over one-fourth are to markets in Brazil and Mexico. Industrial gases 
do not meet either vulnerability criterion, but compared with the other 
examples, have the largest share of imports from China and the most 
pronounced trend of an increased import share from China since 2002. 

[End of section] 

3. Trade Measures: Introduction: 

In this section, we discuss the use of trade measures and output-based 
rebates to address potential competitiveness and environmental effects 
of a domestic emissions pricing system. Through trade measures, such as 
a border tax adjustment or a border allowance requirement, 
international competitors without comparable climate policies would pay 
for greenhouse gas emissions associated with their exports to the 
United States. Output-based rebates have been proposed as another type 
of measure to offset the costs of climate policy for sectors that are 
exposed to unregulated competition through payments based on a per-unit 
government rebate or tax credit, or a per-unit allocation of emissions 
allowances. 

How a trade measure is ultimately designed will have important 
implications for the effectiveness of the overall measure in addressing 
industry and environmental effects. In terms of output based rebates, 
the extent and design of the rebates could help address the industry 
effects, but could also affect the costs to other industries. 

In this section we provide explanations of key features of trade and 
output-based measures included in climate change legislation introduced 
between April 2007 and June 2009. We also provide information on a 
range of views regarding the value of trade and output-based measures 
as policy tools to address competitiveness and environmental concerns. 
Additionally, we provide information on the potential implementation 
challenges associated with implementing these measures. 

3.1. Trade Measures: Different Types: 

American Electric and Power Border Allowance Requirement: 

Some of the climate change bills introduced between April 2007 and June 
2009 included provisions for a border allowance requirement. A border 
allowance requirement proposal was developed by the American Electric 
Power (AEP) and trade union representatives with the International 
Brotherhood of Electric Workers (IBEW). The AEP/IBEW proposal was 
introduced in July 2007 in S. 1766, 110TH Cong. (2007) and was also 
included in various other legislative proposals. 

Trade measures have been proposed to address competitiveness and 
environmental effects associated with implementing a domestic emissions 
pricing system, such as a cap-and-trade system or a carbon tax system. 
Generally, in the context of a domestic emissions pricing system, trade 
measures would impose a cost or other requirement on energy-intensive 
imports from countries with weaker climate policies. Various types of 
trade measures exist for addressing competitiveness effects associated 
with a domestic emissions pricing system. Among the cap-and-trade and 
carbon tax legislative proposals we examined, border tax adjustments or 
border allowance requirements are the most frequently proposed type of 
trade measures. 

Border Tax Adjustment: 

According to experts, a border tax adjustment is a levy applied by the 
federal government, on certain imported goods at the border. Key 
features of a border tax adjustment include the following: 

* Tax proportionate to the imports' embedded carbon: Generally, the tax 
applied to the import would be based on the carbon emissions associated 
with the production of the imported good. 

* Tax equivalent to domestic compliance costs: Generally, the federal 
government would charge imported goods the equivalent of what a 
domestic producer of a similar good would pay to comply with a domestic 
emissions pricing system. 

Border Allowance Requirement: 

According to experts, a border allowance requirement is a measure that 
would require importers to purchase allowances from the federal 
government prior to importing goods into the United States. Generally, 
key features of a border allowance requirement include the following: 

* Establishes a separate pool of allowances: In some of the cap-and-
trade bills proposed in 2008, the federal government would establish a 
reserve of allowances separate from allowances established in the 
domestic cap-and-trade system. The border allowances that importers 
would be required to submit would come from this reserve allowance 
pool. 

* Comparable action determination: Importers of goods from foreign 
countries that do not take "comparable action" to the United States to 
limit greenhouse gas emissions, would be required to submit allowances 
to accompany exports to the United States of the covered good. 

* Documentation at the border: Prior to entering the United States, 
importers would have to purchase allowances from the federal 
government, and submit a written declaration at the border stating that 
the good is accompanied by the required number of allowances. 
Generally, the number of allowances required would be proportionate to 
the embedded carbon content of the import. 

3.1. Trade Measures: Supporters' Views: 

Some policy analysts, industry stakeholders, climate change experts, 
and government officials argue that trade measures help address 
competitiveness and environmental effects associated with domestic 
emissions pricing systems. For example, some supporters contend that 
trade measures may do the following: 

* Prevent a decline in output by U.S. producers: Trade measures would 
help level the playing field by imposing similar costs on imports from 
countries without comparable carbon mitigation policies. The potential 
exists for certain U.S. firms to lose business to energy-intensive 
imports from countries with weaker climate policies. Moreover, firms 
could further lose international competitiveness due to the indirect 
costs of purchasing more expensive U.S. energy. As a result, U.S. firms 
in vulnerable industries could suffer a loss in output, profits, and 
employment. 

* Prevent carbon leakage: Trade measures would prevent U.S. energy- 
intensive industries from shifting production to countries without 
comparable carbon mitigation policies, resulting in carbon leakage, 
where emission reductions in the United States are replaced to some 
degree by production and emission growth in less regulated countries. 
Supporters of trade measures stated that carbon leakage could lead to 
higher volumes of greenhouse gas emissions worldwide. 

* Create leverage on other countries to reduce emissions: Trade 
measures would create incentives for major trading partners to adopt 
similar climate policies. For example, proponents of trade measures 
argue that trade measures could potentially provide leverage to U.S. 
climate negotiators in their efforts to establish a global framework 
that includes other major emitting nations. Some industry stakeholders 
with whom we spoke, for example, stated that the potential benefit of a 
trade measure in increasing pressure on developing countries may trump 
its adverse economic effects. These stakeholders said that countries' 
statements of opposition to proposed trade measures provided evidence 
of their effectiveness in providing leverage. 

* Political acceptability: If a climate change bill is to pass, it will 
be necessary that the bill include a provision like a trade measure to 
address competitiveness effects. Policy experts stated that most 
climate change proposals with trade measures have garnered support from 
industries that could be affected by a domestic emissions pricing 
system. 

3.1. Trade Measures: Opponents' Views: 

Some policy analysts, climate change experts, and government officials 
raise concerns that trade measures may motivate retaliatory actions, 
undermine efforts to secure multilateral consensus, and generate little 
leverage. For example, some opponents contend that trade measures may 
do the following: 

* Motivate retaliatory action: An important implication of U.S. trade 
measures is how they would be perceived by other countries and impact 
negotiations aimed toward an international climate agreement. Opponents 
argued that trade measures could be viewed by other countries as an 
antagonistic step, and could lead to retaliatory action from other 
countries. 

* Undermine efforts to secure international consensus: While there is 
general agreement that the global scope of the climate change problem 
will require actions from all major emitting nations, there are 
differing views on the impact that trade measures may have in securing 
an international consensus. Foreign government officials with whom we 
spoke, declined to give formal positions on trade measure proposals 
given that a climate change bill has not yet passed Congress. But some 
officials expressed concerns over the unilateral application of a trade 
measure by the United States and said that competitiveness effects 
would be better addressed through multilateral discussions. Because 
multilateral approaches involve commitments to reduce greenhouse gas 
emissions by more than one country, they also level the playing field. 
Multilateral approaches include international agreements, such as the 
Kyoto Protocol, or international action, as when countries 
independently decide to reduce their emissions of greenhouse gases. 
Multilateral approaches may involve sectoral agreements, leveling the 
playing field worldwide within an industry. Foreign embassy officials 
also stated that trade measures are not likely to be effective tool to 
leverage other countries to take steps to reduce emissions and that a 
unilateral U.S. trade measure could add to the challenge of developing 
multilateral consensus on climate change mitigation efforts. 

* Generate little leverage on other countries to reduce emissions: The 
effectiveness of trade measures in creating leverage on foreign 
countries to reduce emissions will vary with the share of their output 
that is imported into the United States compared with the share that is 
consumed domestically or exported to other countries. In addition, some 
policy experts we spoke to note that in some cases, the emission costs 
that foreign firms will have to pay on their imports into the United 
States may not be sufficient to motivate them to change domestic 
production processes. For example, in each of the vulnerable industries 
listed in table 2, less than 1 percent of total Chinese output is 
imported into the United States, although the share may be higher for 
individual firms. Instead, most of the Chinese output in these 
industries is consumed domestically or in countries that may or may not 
impose a domestic emissions pricing system. Nonetheless, in certain 
cases, a U.S. trade measure may be effective in providing some degree 
of leverage. For example, U.S. iron and steel imports represent more 
than 8 percent of output in Brazil and more than 10 percent of output 
in Mexico. In addition, U.S. imports of nitrogenous fertilizers from 
the Middle East are more than 20 percent of production from that 
region. 

Table 2: U.S. Imports as a Share of Foreign Output (percentage of 
metric tons): 

Brazil: 
Iron and steel: 8.3; 
Primary aluminum: 5.0; 
Cement: 1.1; 
Pulp products: 10.8; 
Nitrogenous fertilizers: 3.5. 

China: 
Iron and steel: 0.5; 
Primary aluminum: 0.3; 
Cement: 0.9; 
Pulp products: 0.1; 
Nitrogenous fertilizers: 0.5. 

India: 
Iron and steel: 0.7; 
Primary aluminum: 0.0; 
Cement: 0.0; 
Pulp products: n/a; 
Nitrogenous fertilizers: 0.0. 

Mexico: 
Iron and steel: 10.6; 
Primary aluminum: n/a; 
Cement: 5.6; 
Pulp products: 1.1; 
Nitrogenous fertilizers: 8.3. 

Middle East: 
Iron and steel: 0.1; 
Primary aluminum: 6.5; 
Cement: 0.2; 
Pulp products: 0.0; 
Nitrogenous fertilizers: 22.1. 

Source: GAO analysis of production data from the U.S. Geological Survey 
and the Food and Agriculture Organization and trade data from the 
Department of Commerce. 

Notes to Table: 

Data are for 2007, except for cement and nitrogenous fertilizers with 
data for 2006. 

Iron and steel production figures include those for pig iron, direct- 
reduced iron, and raw steel. 

Cement production figures are for hydraulic cement. 

Pulp products production figures represent the total for "pulp for 
paper" products within FAOSTAT. 

Nitrogenous fertilizer production figures represent tonnage by total 
nutrients within FAOSTAT. 

Not included in the iron and steel import figures above were about 38 
million liters from Mexico. 

[End of table] 

3.1. Trade Measures: Implementation Challenges: 

Trade measures could present implementation challenges, particularly 
with obtaining necessary data to measure the carbon content of imports, 
and to evaluate and assess climate change actions of other countries. 
Examples of potential implementation challenges include the following: 

* Determining the embedded carbon content in imports: Generally, 
imposing a trade measure on an import would require a determination of 
the embedded carbon content, or the amount of greenhouse gases emitted 
during the production of the imported good. According to experts, 
accurately measuring the embedded carbon content for specific items 
would be challenging. Furthermore, climate policy experts point out 
that while determining the embedded carbon content in standardized 
products like steel, primary aluminum, and basic chemicals would be 
difficult, it would be even more challenging to assess the embedded 
carbon content of products that rely on these goods for final assembly. 

Additionally, climate policy experts noted that, variations in the type 
of energy used can result in different carbon intensities for goods 
that appear identical at the border. To accurately assess the embedded 
carbon content of a product, the administrator of the program would be 
required to obtain specific plant-level information on the production 
process of the import from foreign countries. 

Accurately measuring the embedded carbon content of an import would 
require significant data, resulting in several data reliability 
concerns with obtaining carbon data from international inventories. 
Experts and industry stakeholders alike reported that obtaining data 
from foreign producers could be a challenge, and that using data from 
international inventories could raise several data reliability concerns 
as the United States would have no way of verifying that the data 
obtained was accurate. In addition, under the S. 3036 110TH Cong. 
(2008), importers would have to submit a declaration statement at the 
border declaring the imported good is accompanied by the required 
number of allowances. Agency officials we spoke to noted that officials 
would not know if the information contained in the declaration was 
accurate. 

* Evaluating and assessing climate change actions: As previously 
discussed, a key feature of a trade measure provision is the 
requirement of determining the comparability of other countries' 
actions to address climate change. According to policy experts, among 
some of the cap-and-trade bills introduced, some have not clearly 
defined or assessed the method for determining how other countries' 
actions on climate change would be assess by the U.S. government. In 
order for the implementing agency to assess the comparability of 
different countries, the criteria for making this determination would 
have to be defined either in the legislation or implementing 
regulations. 

3.1. Trade Measures: Design Trade-Offs: 

In designing a trade measure, there are a range of possible options to 
consider as illustrated in table 3. The design features of trade 
measures involve different trade-offs that will have implications for 
the effectiveness of the overall measure in addressing competitiveness 
and environmental concerns. 

For example, a key design consideration is the timing for when the 
trade measure would go into effect. Delaying the implementation of the 
trade measure could result in the measure being a more effective 
leverage tool because it would provide other countries with an 
opportunity to implement similar carbon mitigation policies. On the 
other hand, industry stakeholders with whom we spoke argued that a 
delay in implementing the trade measure could adversely affect U.S. 
industries by incurring costs under a domestic emissions pricing system 
that their foreign competitors would not face. According to some 
stakeholders, this could result in U.S. industries being at a 
competitive disadvantage compared to foreign competitors. 

The method for determining the comparability of other countries' 
actions also involves important trade-offs. Given the different 
approaches being utilized to address climate change, questions have 
been raised over whether these different actions would be deemed 
comparable to U.S. efforts. Industry groups have argued that the method 
for determining comparability should be based on quantitative criteria 
that are equivalent to criteria U.S. producers must meet. However, 
providing flexibility on determining comparability allows countries to 
utilize the approach best suited for reducing emissions in their 
individual country. 

Table 3: Policy Experts Cite Trade-offs Involved in the Design of Trade 
Measures: 

Feature: Date when the trade measure goes into effect; 
Options: The trade measure can go into effect simultaneously when a 
domestic cap-and-trade system goes into effect or at a later date; 
Design trade-offs: Having the trade measure go into effect 
simultaneously when the domestic cap-and-trade system goes into effect 
may reduce impacts on U.S. industry competitiveness. Delaying the 
implementation of the trade measure allows time for international 
climate negotiations and for countries to take action on reducing their 
emissions. 

Feature: Type of products covered; 
Options: Climate bills in the 110th Congress limited coverage of the 
trade measure to specified products such as importers of steel, 
aluminum, and cement; whereas other bills expanded coverage to 
manufactured goods that met eligibility criteria; 
Design trade-offs: Limiting product coverage may exclude industries 
vulnerable to competitiveness effects. Expanding product coverage 
increases federal challenges to track emissions. 

Feature: Defining comparable action; 
Options: Proposals have varied in stringency and level of detail in 
outlining the methodology for determining comparable action; 
Design trade-offs: Quantitative criteria for assessing comparable 
action may not measure the level of effort on climate policy that a 
country actually undertakes. Flexibility and discretion on 
comparability determinations increases uncertainty for industry 
stakeholders. 

Feature: Calculating border allowance requirements; 
Options: Proposals have varied in the level of detail in outlining the 
methodology for calculating the number of allowances industries will be 
required to submit at the border. Earlier proposals based border 
allowance requirements on averages for country industry sectors; H.R. 
2454 delegated the decision to the future implementing agency; 
Design trade-offs: Basing border allowance requirements on industry 
average increases implementation feasibility as firm-level data likely 
not available; Using industry average for baseline may limit incentives 
to improve efficiency and would penalize efficient firms. 

Source: GAO analysis of selected climate change legislation introduced 
between April 2007 and June 2009 that included trade measures. 

[End of table] 

3.2. Trade Measures: Alternative: Output-Based Rebates: 

Output-based rebates have been proposed as policy alternatives to using 
trade measures. These rebates would be provided to energy-intensive (or 
greenhouse gas-intensive) and trade-exposed industries to cover their 
increased costs from the carbon pricing system. Under legislative 
proposals, EPA would determine the average energy (or greenhouse gas) 
intensity per unit of production for each relevant industrial sector 
and then distribute allowances based on each facility's amount of 
production. Although some industry stakeholders note that output-based 
rebates address competitiveness effects by compensating covered firms 
for incurred costs, some climate policy experts note that output-based 
rebates could distort pricing, could reduce incentives for firms to 
engage in conservation, and may drive up the cost of the program. 

Output-based Rebates: 

Output-based rebates are measures designed to financially rebate 
industries for the costs incurred under a domestic emissions pricing 
system. According to policy experts, key features of an output-based 
rebate include the following: 

* Tied to firm's level of output: Generally, output-based rebates would 
be tied to a firm's level of output. For example, firms that expand 
their operations will receive a larger rebate, while firms that 
downsize but continue to produce in the United States will receive a 
smaller rebate. Firms that move offshore or shut down would receive no 
rebate. A rebate can take the form of a per-unit rebate or tax credit, 
or a per-unit allocation of emissions allowances. 

* Compensates for incurred costs: For a facility with an average level 
of energy intensity (or greenhouse gas intensity) these rebates would 
cover both direct and indirect costs. These would include their own 
emissions and costs associated with higher energy prices and technology 
purchases to improve energy efficiency. Providing allowances based on 
average industry intensity, energy intensity and production levels, 
rather than providing them based on each firm's historical emissions, 
is intended to reward the most efficient facilities and create an 
incentive for continued efficiency improvements. 

H.R. 2454 111THCong. (2009) included provisions for output-based 
rebates to offset the costs incurred by firms to comply with a cap-and- 
trade system. Two other climate change bills, H.R. 7146, 110tTHCong. 
(2008) and H.R. 1759, 111tTHCong. (2009), also incorporated output- 
based rebates. In all three proposals, allowances would be distributed 
among certain energy-and trade-intensive industries according to an 
individual firm's output. 

Supporters' Views: 

Some policy analysts, climate change experts, and government officials 
argue that output-based rebates may address some of the limitations 
associated with using trade measures. For example, some supporters 
contend that output-based rebates may do the following: 

* Mitigate costs incurred by U.S. producers: Output-based rebates are 
necessary to compensate U.S. firms for costs incurred while complying 
with a domestic emissions pricing system. Supporters note that trade 
measures only apply costs to foreign competitors at the border, while 
output-based rebates affect producers' costs for both domestic and 
export markets. Among the key supporters of output-based rebates are 
stakeholders in energy-intensive industries who note that energy costs 
are a substantial portion of their manufacturing costs. According to 
these stakeholders, proposals that mitigate costs at the production 
level, either by allocating free allowances to qualifying facilities or 
rebating the costs of allowances offsets the disincentive created by 
higher energy prices in the United States. 

* Reward efficient firms: Output-based rebates are generally allocated 
in proportion to current levels of production rather than being fixed 
to historical measures. Supporters argue that because the rebates or 
allocations are tied to production levels, individual firms have an 
incentive to increase their production. According to supporters, 
rebates reward the most productive plants and stimulate investments in 
efficient technology. Moreover, the rebates would benefit firms that 
face competition from foreign suppliers in markets at home or global 
export markets or both. 

* Use U.S. data: Implementing output-based rebates may be more 
manageable than implementing trade measures. For example, in proposed 
legislation, agencies would only require data from U.S. data sources to 
identify firms that would be eligible for output-based rebates. This 
differs from trade measures which would require data from foreign 
firms' production, which could be more difficult to obtain. In 
addition, legislative proposals have generally been explicit about the 
U.S. data sources and criteria to be used in identifying eligible 
industries. 

Opponents' Views: 

Some policy analysts, climate change experts, and government officials 
argue that despite several advantages identified with using output- 
based rebates, several potential limitations also exist. For example, 
some opponents contend that output-based rebates offset the costs of 
climate policy for sectors that are exposed to unregulated competition, 
and thereby lower the incentives for those firms to engage in 
conservation and reduce their energy intensity. Similarly, output-based 
rebates would likely result in relatively lower output prices for the 
products produced by firms receiving rebates, thereby reducing the 
incentives for consumers of those products to conserve. Moreover, some 
climate policy experts argue that output-based rebates create a subsidy 
for certain energy-intensive industries which would require non energy- 
intensive firms to engage in greater efforts to reduce the emissions 
intensity of their production. 

Potential Implementation Challenges: 

Although the data requirements for an output-based measure may be more 
manageable than those of a trade measure, some challenges related to 
identifying electricity distribution data exist. For example, under HR 
2454, 111TH Cong. (2009), EPA would be required to obtain production 
data on various commodities from energy-intensive industries, including 
electricity distribution data. Data on electricity use on a facility- 
by-facility basis is not currently collected by government agencies. 
Provisions in either the legislation or in implementing regulations 
would have to be explicit on how to obtain data on electricity use. 

Additionally, according to EPA officials, the methodology outlined in 
HR 2454, 111TH Cong. (2009), for how to determine eligible industries 
does not align with data that would be collected under EPA's proposed 
mandatory greenhouse gas reporting rule. According to climate policy 
experts, standard mechanisms for reviewing eligibility for the rebates 
are needed to ensure that the policy does not over compensate certain 
industries. 

3.3. Trade Measures: Legislative History Of Trade Measures And Output-
Based Rebates: 

Between April 2007 and June 2009, several cap-and-trade and carbon tax 
bills were introduced with provisions to address the potential 
competitiveness and environmental effects of implementing a domestic 
emissions pricing system. For example, of the cap-and-trade bills that 
we examined and that were introduced during that period, some included 
trade measures such as an allowance requirement at the border or a 
border tax. 

As illustrated in figure 19, two bills introduced in 2009 have included 
provisions for using output-based rebates. The most recent bill, H.R. 
2454, 111th Cong. (2009) includes a provision for output-based rebates. 
Under that bill, energy intensive and trade exposed industries would 
receive allowances to cover their increased costs. 

Several industry stakeholders with whom we spoke, reported that output- 
based rebates and trade measures could function as complimentary 
measures to address competitiveness concerns. For example, in H.R. 
2454, 111THCong. (2009), the output-based rebates would be phased out 
by 2035 unless the President decides to extend them. In that bill, the 
trade measure would go into effect after 2020, unless the President 
determines it would not be in the national interest and Congress passes 
an affirmative joint resolution within 90 days. 

Some stakeholders have stated that having the trade measure to go into 
effect at a later time may provide time for the United States to be 
part of international negotiations on climate change. 

Figure 19: Proposals Move toward Using Output-Based Rebates to Address 
Competitiveness Concerns: 

[Refer to PDF for image: illustrated timeline] 

Border tax adjustment: 
110th Congress:
HR 2069 (Stark), introduced April, 2007; 
HR 3416 (Larson), introduced August, 2007. 
111th Congress: 
HR 1337 (Larson), introduced March, 2009. 

Border allowance requirement: 
110th Congress: 
S. 1776 (Bingaman-Spector), introduced July, 2007; 
S. 3036 (Boxer-Lieberman-Warner), introduced May, 2008; 
HR 6186 (Markey), introduced June 4, 2008; 
HR 6316 (Doggett), introduced June, 2008. 

Output-based rebates: 
110th Congress: 
HR 7146 (Inslee-Doyle), introduced September, 2008; 
111th Congress: 
HR 1759 (Inslee-Doyle), introduced March, 2009. 

Output-based measure with potential border allowance requirement: 
111th Congress: 
HR 2454 (Waxman-Markey), passed in House, June 2009. 

Source: GAO analysis. 

[End of figure] 

4. International Trade Implications: Overview: 

Introduction: 

In this section, we discuss potential international implications of a 
U.S. trade measure, such as concerns about countries possibly 
retaliating in response to a trade measure or its potential impact on 
the multilateral trading system. In addition, we provide information on 
the WTO dispute settlement process, a forum that facilitates the 
resolution of specific trade disputes. We provide information on the 
WTO provisions and key questions that may apply if a U.S. trade measure 
or an output-based rebate were to be challenged at the WTO. 

Assessing the international trade implications is difficult for a 
number of reasons. One is that it depends in part upon how other 
nations reduce their carbon emissions, and whether they perceive any 
U.S. measures as likely to affect their exports. In addition, the 
outcome of a WTO challenge, if any, would be uncertain and may depend 
on how the measure is implemented. 

Potential Bilateral and Multilateral Trade Impacts: 

According to experts and foreign officials we spoke with, U.S. climate 
change trade measures may have implications for U.S. and multilateral 
trade relations. 

* Potential for bilateral trade retaliation: Countries may view U.S. 
trade measures as trade restrictions or sanctions, which could lead 
them to implement restrictions against U.S. exports. Other countries 
could potentially develop counter measures based on a different test of 
"comparability," such as historical or per capita emissions, according 
to trade experts we spoke with. 

Although no other country has yet to implement a trade measure based on 
greenhouse gas emissions, European officials have previously considered 
the use of trade measures on countries, including the United States, 
that have not taken actions that match European standards. In addition, 
support within other countries for imposing trade measures could 
increase if the United States implements a trade measure. 

* Potential for increased trade tensions: A broader concern is that 
escalating retaliation between the United States and other countries 
could lead to significant global trade tensions. Given the volume of 
trade in goods that could potentially be affected by trade measures 
linked to greenhouse gas emissions, some officials and experts have 
argued that escalating tensions and responses to these measures could 
ultimately do significant harm to the functioning of the multilateral 
trading system under the WTO. Trade experts told us that trade measures 
and responses could potentially pose systemic challenges to the WTO and 
its dispute resolution system. For example, multiple challenges brought 
up by other countries based on different imported products could tie up 
the system. 

4.1. International Trade Implications: WTO Compliance Questions: 

WTO Dispute Settlement Process: 

* Consultation (up to 60 days); 

* Panel Review (generally up to 6 months, but in no case more than 9 
months); 

* Appellate Stage (60 to 90 days); 

* DSB Decision (generally up to 9 months and up to 12 months if the 
panel report is appealed); 

* Implementation Stage (if immediate compliance is impractical, member 
given a 'reasonable period of time' to comply, which normally should 
not exceed 15 months from adoption of report up to 15 months). 

A unilateral U.S. trade measure or system of rebates linked to a 
climate change policy may be challenged by other countries through the 
WTO's dispute resolution process. Countries could potentially raise 
different types of challenges depending on the design of the trade 
measure or rebate, and several key questions may be relevant in the 
consideration of a WTO dispute. These questions stem from the WTO 
provisions under which the trade measures or rebates may be challenged 
and reviewed, including the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 
(GATT), and the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Duties 
(ASCM). 

The following pages describe in more detail the questions, factors, and 
WTO provisions listed in table 4. 

WTO Dispute Settlement Process: 

The WTO's dispute settlement system facilitates the resolution of 
specific trade disputes and serves as a vehicle for upholding trade 
rules and preserving the rights and obligations of WTO Members under 
WTO agreements. WTO Members may request consultations concerning 
measures affecting the operation of such WTO agreements. After 
consultations, WTO Members can request the establishment of a panel to 
hear their claims regarding alleged inconsistencies of other Member's 
measures. The panel will issue a report of its findings, which will be 
adopted by the WTO Dispute Settlement Body (DSB), unless a party to the 
dispute appeals the panel's report, which is reviewed by the WTO 
Appellate Body. WTO disputes can take several years or more to complete 
the entire process. If the responding party does not prevail and fails 
to comply with the rulings and recommendations of the DSB, the 
complaining party may seek authority to suspend concessions or other 
obligations under the WTO agreements. 

Table 4: Key Questions That May be Considered in a WTO Challenge: 

Key questions: 1. Is the trade measure consistent with WTO market 
access requirements? 
Discussion: Customs duties or other duties or charges on imports in 
excess of schedules of concessions may not be imposed. Subject to 
exceptions, prohibitions or restrictions, other than duties, taxes or 
other charges, on imports may not be imposed; 
WTO provisions: GATT Article II, XI. 

Key questions: 2. Is the trade measure consistent with WTO non-
discrimination requirements? 
Discussion: Measure must treat imported products no less favorably than 
like domestic products; 
WTO provisions: GATT Article III. 

Key questions: 2. Is the trade measure consistent with WTO non-
discrimination requirements? 
Discussion: Measure must also not discriminate among goods from 
different countries; 
WTO provisions: GATT Article I. 

Key questions: 3. If not WTO consistent, is the trade measure covered 
by a WTO environmental exception? 
Discussion: Measure relating to conservation of exhaustible natural 
resources or that is necessary to protect human, animal or plant health 
is covered under WTO exceptions; 
WTO provisions: GATT Article XX (b), (g). 

Key questions: 3. If not WTO consistent, is the trade measure covered 
by a WTO environmental exception? 
Discussion: To be covered, measure must not be applied in a manner 
which would constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable 
discrimination or be a disguised restriction on international trade; 
WTO provisions: GATT Article XX chapeau. 

Key questions: 4. Are output-based rebates consistent with WTO rules 
governing subsidies? 
Discussion: The rebates must not involve a specific subsidy or other 
benefit that causes adverse effects to other WTO Members; 
WTO provisions: ASCM. 

Source: GAO analysis of legal scholars' views on questions and 
provisions that may be relevant in analyzing trade measures contained 
in climate change legislation for consistency with WTO rules. 

[End of table] 

4.1. International Trade Implications: WTO Compliance: 

The following observations are based on comments from various legal 
scholars and other non-governmental commentators on questions and 
provisions that may be relevant in analyzing trade measures contained 
in climate change legislation for consistency with WTO rules. 

1. Is the Trade Measure Consistent with WTO Market Access Rules and 
Commitments? 

An initial question involves how a trade measure would be interpreted 
and the corresponding GATT article under which the measure would be 
reviewed. 

* GATT Article II:1(b) prohibits a WTO Member from applying customs 
duties or other duties or charges to imports in excess of the Member's 
schedule of tariff concessions. 

* GATT Article XI:1 prohibits prohibitions or restrictions, other than 
duties, taxes or other charges, on imports, with certain exceptions. 

* According to legal experts, a "border tax" imposed on imports 
equivalent to a tax imposed on like domestic products may be WTO 
compliant. 

2. Is the Trade Measure Consistent with WTO Non-Discrimination 
Requirements? 

Trade measures must also be consistent with WTO non-discrimination 
provisions covering most favored nation status treatment and national 
treatment. 

* Does a trade measure treat two like products differently depending on 
country of origin? GATT Article I:1 provides, in part, that with 
respect to customs duties and charges imposed on or in connection with 
importation and exportation, and the method of levying such duties and 
charges, any advantage granted by any WTO Member to any product 
originating in any other Member is to be accorded immediately and 
unconditionally to the like product originating in or destined for all 
other WTO Members. 

* Does a trade measure treat imported products less favorably than like 
domestic products? GATT Article III:4 provides, in part, that imported 
products shall be accorded treatment no less favorable than that 
accorded to like products of national origin in respect of all laws, 
regulations, and requirements affecting their internal sale, offering 
for sale, purchase, transportation, distribution, or use. 

Shrimp-Turtle Case - In this 1996 case, four WTO members challenged as 
discriminatory a U.S. embargo on the importation of certain shrimp and 
shrimp products from countries that had not been certified by the 
Department of State as having a comprehensive sea turtle conservation 
regime. The United States argued that the measure was justified under 
article XX (g). 

However, the WTO panel found, in part, that the U.S. measure was not 
justified under article XX (g) because it met the panel's test of being 
a "risk to the multilateral trading system." Upon appeal, the Appellate 
Body rejected the panel's test and found that the measure fell within 
article XX (g). However, the Appellate Body also found the U.S. measure 
had been applied in an arbitrary and discriminatory manner. 

The United States was ultimately able to comply with WTO rulings by 
making changes in the way the law was administered, including revising 
guidelines to establish greater transparency and due process in country 
certification decisions. 

3. If the Trade Measure Is Not Permissible Under Core WTO Obligations, 
Would it Be Covered Under an Environmental Exception? 

If a trade measure does not comply with GATT market access or non- 
discrimination provisions, it may still be justified under certain GATT 
environmental exceptions. A key consideration would be the 
interpretation of the intended purpose of the measure and whether it is 
designed to serve an environmental objective. 

* Is the trade measure designed to serve an environmental objective? 

- GATT Article XX (b) provides an exception for measures necessary to 
protect human, animal, or plant life or health. 

- GATT Article XX (g) provides an exception for measures relating to 
the conservation of exhaustible natural resources if such measures are 
made effective in conjunction with restrictions on domestic production 
or consumption. 

* How is the measure applied? The introduction (chapeau) to GATT 
Article XX states that such measures must not be applied in a manner 
that would constitute a means of arbitrary or unjustifiable 
discrimination or a disguised restriction on international trade. 

4. Are Output-Based Rebates Consistent with WTO Rules Governing 
Subsidies? 

The ASCM imposes disciplines on certain kinds of subsidies to domestic 
producers, such as those that cause adverse effects to foreign 
competitors. 

* Is an output-based rebate or distribution of free allowances a 
subsidy? To be considered a subsidy under the ASCM, a system of rebates 
would need to involve (1) a "financial contribution" by the government 
or any form of income or price support that (2) confers a "benefit" to 
the recipient and (3) is "specific." 

* Is the rebate an "actionable" subsidy that causes "adverse effects" 
to the interests of other WTO Members? A further key question is 
whether a rebate, if found to be a subsidy, would cause "serious 
prejudice" to the interests of other WTO Members. 

[End of section] 

Appendix 1: Objectives, Scope, And Methodology: 

Our research objectives were to examine: (1) information on estimating 
industry effects; (2) examples of industries that may be vulnerable to 
a loss in international competitiveness from emissions pricing; (3) 
trade measures and other approaches to address competitiveness issues; 
and (4) potential international implications of trade measures. 

To address all of these objectives, we (1) reviewed relevant climate 
change academic literature and federal agency documents; (2) reviewed 
and analyzed studies and data on climate change from a variety of 
sources, including past GAO work, the U.S. Census Bureau and 
Departments of Commerce and Energy, international organizations, policy 
institutes, and universities; (3) interviewed agency officials from the 
Office of the U.S. Trade Representative (USTR); the Environmental 
Protection Agency (EPA); the Departments of Commerce, State, Energy, 
and Treasury, and the Department of Homeland Security's Customs and 
Border Protection (CBP); (4) conducted interviews with subject-matter 
experts selected from a population of individuals from government, 
academia, business, and professional organizations. Several criteria 
were used for selecting experts to interview including: type and depth 
of experience, the expert's recognition in the professional community, 
relevance of published work, professional affiliations, present and 
past positions held, and other subject matter experts' recommendations. 

Objective 1 and 2: 

To better understand how implementing a domestic emissions pricing 
system would likely affect the international competitiveness of U.S 
industries, we reviewed relevant studies from GAO, EPA, the Department 
of Energy's Energy Information Agency (EIA), and international 
organizations. We also reviewed documents and interviewed experts from 
policy institutes, universities, and industry. 

Recently proposed legislation identifies industries potentially 
vulnerable to adverse competitiveness effects as those with: (a) either 
energy intensity or greenhouse gas intensity of 5 percent or greater; 
and (b) a trade intensity of 15 percent or greater.[Footnote 4] Since 
calculation of greenhouse gas intensity requires an emissions price-- 
not yet determined--and detailed industry data on greenhouse gas 
emissions--not currently available--we focus our analysis on industry 
energy intensity. However, energy intensity is also an imperfect 
measure of potential vulnerability since energy use is not the only 
source of industrial greenhouse gas emissions, and an industry's energy 
expenditures may rise with to a change in market prices, even if the 
industry's greenhouse emissions decline. Additionally, many factors may 
determine the vulnerability of any particular firm, including 
transportation costs, supply chain relationships, and access to markets 
for natural resources, capital, or labor. 

Based on industry and expert studies, most industries that meet both 
vulnerability criteria are within primary metals, nonmetallic minerals, 
paper products, and chemicals.[Footnote 5] Quantitative analysis of the 
estimated competitiveness impacts of U.S. greenhouse gas emissions 
pricing is relatively limited. We present results for two studies that 
separate the international competitiveness effects from U.S. emissions 
pricing from the domestic market effects. Estimated results from these 
two studies include findings that are broadly consistent with those of 
other studies. For example, a study of climate policy impacts on U.S. 
industries was commissioned by the National Committee on Energy Policy 
and studies of the European Union's climate policies have been 
performed for the European Commission and the International Energy 
Agency. In each of these studies, the list of vulnerable industries is 
generally consistent, as is the finding that estimated impacts could be 
greater for energy-intensive industries. 

To illustrate variation in economic characteristics among these four 
manufacturing industries, we analyzed: (1) energy consumption data from 
the U.S. Census Bureau's Annual Survey of Manufacturers; (2) energy use 
data from EIA's Manufacturing Energy Consumption Survey; (3) 
international trade data from the Department of Commerce's 
International Trade Administration; and (4) U.S. and international 
production data from the Department of Commerce's Bureau of Economic 
Analysis, the U.S. Geological Survey and the United Nations Food and 
Agricultural Organization (FAO). For analysis of sub-industries, we 
examined data with a Census Bureau North American Industry 
Classification System (NAICS) code of 5 to 6 digits, depending on how 
the data were reported in each of the databases reviewed and for 
consistency of comparison with other studies. For the vulnerable sub- 
industry charts, we applied multiple criteria to show variation in 
industry characteristics of energy intensity, trade intensity, and 
primary trading partners. For example, we selected sub-industries that 
met both the energy and trade intensity criteria, examples that met 
only one criterion, and examples that met neither, but had significant 
imports from non-Annex I countries. We do not identify the complete 
list of potentially vulnerable sub-industries, a list that will vary 
depending on the level of aggregation in product lines that is 
examined. The specific list of example sub-industries we selected, 
along with their corresponding NAICS codes can be found in table 5. 

Table 5: Sub-Industries Selected as Vulnerable Industry Examples: 

Sub-Industry Examples: Primary Metals; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 331. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Iron and steel mills; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 331111. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Electrometallurgical products; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 331112. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Steel manufacturing; 33121, 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 33122. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Ferrous metal foundries; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 33151. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Primary aluminum; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 331312. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Aluminum products; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 331314, 331316. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Nonmetallic Minerals; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 327. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Cement; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32731. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Concrete; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32732. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Lime and gypsum; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 3274. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Glass; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32721. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Clay building material; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32712. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Mineral wool; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 327993. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Paper Products; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 322. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Pulp mills; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32211. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Paper mills; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32212. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Paperboard mills; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32213. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Paperboard containers; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32221. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Chemicals; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 325. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Alkalies and chlorine; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 325181. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Carbon black; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 325182. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Nitrogenous fertilizers; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 325311. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Industrial gases; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32512. 

Sub-Industry Examples: Artificial and synthetic fibers; 
North American Industry Classification System Codes: 32522. 

Source: U.S. Census Bureau, [hyperlink, 
http://www.census.gov/eos/www/naics/]. 

[End of table] 

We tested the data we analyzed for internal consistency and for 
consistency with other key published studies, interviewed agency and 
industry officials regarding appropriate use of the data, and reviewed 
source data information regarding the entity's methodology and actions 
taken to ensure data reliability. We determined that the data were 
sufficiently reliable for our use. We note, however, that industry 
characteristics may change over time and may vary for firms within each 
sub-industry selected. To supplement our data analysis, we conducted 
interviews with industry groups such as steel, aluminum, chemicals, and 
the Energy-Intensive Manufacturer's Working Group. 

Objective 3: 

To identify and compare key features of proposed trade measures, we 
reviewed and analyzed selected climate change legislation introduced 
between 2007 and 2009, and congressional hearing records. From these 
documents we extracted information regarding features of the trade 
measures, such as objectives, scope of coverage, effective date for 
trade measures, and other key features. To identify how features of 
trade measures could address the potential economic and environmental 
effects of emissions pricing, we reviewed studies and reports obtained 
from our literature review, including past GAO reports on climate 
change and studies published by climate change policy institutes such 
as Resources for the Future, the Peterson Institute, and the Pew Center 
on Global Climate change. We also interviewed subject matter experts 
and agency officials from USTR; EPA; the Departments of Commerce, 
State, Energy, and Treasury, and CBP, regarding these issues and to 
identify the potential implementation and administrative challenges 
with using trade measures. In our interviews with agency officials we 
discussed steps agencies have taken to anticipate implementation 
challenges. To obtain information about climate change policies in 
other countries and to learn about the potential impact of U.S. trade 
measures on bilateral relations and international negotiations, we also 
interviewed officials from the embassies of Australia, Brazil, Canada, 
China, European Union, Mexico, and Singapore. 

Objective 4: 

To assess potential international implications of using trade measures, 
we interviewed subject matter experts, agency officials in EPA, CBP, 
USTR, EIA, and the Departments of Treasury, State, and Commerce, and 
foreign embassy officials. To discuss questions and provisions that may 
be relevant in analyzing trade measures and output-based rebates for 
consistency with WTO rules, we reviewed WTO documents, obtained 
information from our interviews with subject-matter experts and agency 
officials, and reviewed information obtained from our literature 
review. 

USTR provided technical comments on this report. 

We conducted our work from October 2008 to July 2009 in accordance with 
all sections of GAO's Quality Assurance Framework that are relevant to 
our objectives. The framework requires that we plan and perform the 
engagement to obtain sufficient and appropriate evidence to meet our 
stated objectives and to discuss any limitations in our work. We 
believe that the information and data obtained, and the analysis 
conducted, provide a reasonable basis for any findings and conclusions 
in this product. 

[End of section] 

Appendix 2: Notes To Industry Figures: 

Notes to Figure 2: Energy intensity is calculated as the value of 
purchased fuels and electricity as a share of the value of output. 
Trade intensity is calculated as the value of total trade (exports plus 
imports) divided by the value of output plus imports. Data for value of 
output are from the Bureau of Economic Analysis Gross Domestic Product 
(GDP) by industry accounts, shipments by industry in current dollars. 

Notes to Figure 3: Due to aggregation in source data, energy intensity 
for electrometallurgical products is assumed to be the same as iron and 
steel mills. Energy intensity data for primary aluminum is based on 
2005 data. Aluminum products include industries characterized by the 
North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) with codes 331314 
and 331316 and steel manufacturing industries represent codes 33121 and 
33122. 

Notes to Figure 4: Energy types characterized as "Renewables and other" 
includes residual and distillate fuel oil, liquefied petroleum gases, 
natural gas liquids, net steam (the sum of purchases, generation from 
renewables, and net transfers), and other energy that respondents 
indicated was used to produce heat and power or as feedstock/raw 
material inputs. Net electricity is the sum of purchases, transfers in, 
and generation from noncombustible renewable resources minus quantities 
sold and transferred out. Due to aggregation in source data, "Aluminum" 
includes primary aluminum and aluminum products. 

Notes to Figure 5: "EU Plus" includes countries from the EU and other 
Annex I countries not represented elsewhere. Other than China, the 
largest two sources of imports for electrometallurgical products are 
the Republic of South Africa (17 percent) and Trinidad and Tobago (10 
percent). 

Notes to Figure 6: The current value of imports from all countries is 
shown in the table below the chart. 

Notes to Figure 7: Energy intensity data for clay building materials 
are based on 2005 data because 2006 data were not available. Glass 
products include industries characterized by the North American 
Industry Classification System (NAICS) with codes 32721. 

Notes to Figure 8: Energy use by type data for lime products excludes 
gypsum. Data on energy use by nonmetallic mineral sub-industry examples 
excluded from the chart are not currently reported by the Department of 
Energy. 

Notes to Figure 9: After Canada and China, the two largest sources of 
imports for cement are Korea (9 percent) and Colombia (8 percent). 

Notes to Figure 10: The current value of imports from all countries is 
shown in the table below the chart. 

Notes to Figure 11: Due to aggregation in Bureau of Economic Analysis 
value of output data for paper mills with paperboard mills, value of 
output data for these two sub-industries are for 2006 and are from the 
Census Bureau's Annual Survey of Manufacturers, shipments by industry 
in current dollars. Aggregated data for 2006 are consistent between the 
two sources. 

Notes to Figure 12: Data for coal and coke usage by pulp mills are not 
publicly available to avoid disclosure of individual firm information, 
such that percentage shares could not be computed. Data on energy use 
by paperboard containers is not currently reported by the Department of 
Energy. 

Notes to Figure 14: The current value of imports from all countries is 
shown in the table below the chart. 

Notes to Figure 15: Energy intensity data for alkalies and chlorine and 
carbon black is based on 2005 data because 2006 data is currently not 
available. 

Notes to Figure 16: Data for certain energy uses by type for alkalies 
and chlorine, industrial gases, and artificial and synthetic fibers is 
not publicly available to avoid disclosure of individual firm 
information, such that percentage shares could not be computed. 

Notes to Figure 17: Other than Canada, the two largest sources of 
imports for nitrogenous fertilizers are Trinidad and Tobago (26 
percent) and the Middle East (14 percent), with countries in the Middle 
East defined by the U.S. Department of State. 

Notes to Figure 18: The current value of imports from all countries is 
shown in the table below the chart. 

Notes to Figure 19: In addition to these bills, Representatives John 
Dingell and Rick Boucher released a discussion draft on October 7, 
2008. The discussion draft included a cap-and-trade proposal, and 
presents four options for allocating allowances under a cap-and-trade 
system. 

[End of section] 

Appendix 3: Works Cited: 

Aldy, Joseph E. and Pizer, William A. (May, 2009) "The Competitiveness 
Impacts of Climate Change Policies." Pew Center on Global Climate 
Change, Arlington, VA. 

Fischer, Carolyn, and Fox, Alan K. (February, 2009) "Comparing Policies 
to Combat Emissions Leakage: Border Tax Adjustments versus Rebates." 
RFF Discussion Paper No. 09-02, Resources for the Future, Washington, 
D.C. 

GAO, Climate Change: Expert Opinion on the Economics of Policy Options 
to Address Climate Change, [hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-08-605] (Washington, D.C.: May 9, 
2008). 

GAO, International Climate Change Programs: Lessons Learned from the 
European Union's Emissions Trading Scheme and the Kyoto Protocol's 
Clean Development Mechanism, [hyperlink, 
http://www.gao.gov/products/GAO-09-151] (Washington, D.C.: November 18, 
2008). 

Ho, Mun S., Richard Morgenstern, and Jhih-Shyang Shih. (November, 2008) 
"Impact of Carbon Price Policies on U.S. Industry." RFF Discussion 
Paper No. 08-37, Resources for the Future, Washington, D.C. 

U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Atmospheric Programs. 
EPA Preliminary Analysis of the Waxman-Markey Discussion Draft, The 
American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 in the 111th Congress, 
Appendix. April 20, 2009. 

[End of section] 

Appendix 4: Climate Change Bills Cited In Report: 

Save Our Climate Act of 2007, H.R. 2069, 110TH Cong., (2007): 

America's Energy Security Trust Fund Act of 2007, H.R. 3416, 110TH 
Cong., (2007): 

Low Carbon Economy Act of 2007, S. 1766, 110TH Cong., (2007): 

Lieberman-Warner Climate Security Act of 2008, S. 3036, 110TH Cong., 
(2008): 

Investing in Climate Action and Protection Act , H.R. 6186, 110TH 
Cong., (2008): 

Climate Market, Auction, Trust & Trade Emissions Reduction System Act 
of 2008, H.R. 6316, 110TH Cong., (2008): 

Carbon Leakage Prevention Act , H.R. 7146, 110TH Cong., (2008): 

America's Energy Security Trust Fund Act of 2009, 111TH Cong., (2009): 

Emission Migration Prevention with Long-term Output Yields Act , H.R. 
1759, 111TH Cong., (2009): 

American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 , H.R. 2454, 111TH 
Cong., (2009): 

[End of section] 

Appendix 5: Glossary: 

Annex I Countries: Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention 
on Climate Change (UNFCCC) that are industrialized countries and were 
members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development 
(OECD) in 1992 plus countries characterized as economies in transition. 

Allowances: In the context of a cap-and-trade system, an emissions 
allowance is a permit to emit a specific quantity of emissions. 

Border allowance requirement: A measure that would require importers to 
purchase allowances from the federal government prior to importing 
goods into the United States. 

Border tax adjustment: A levy on imported goods proportionate to the 
imports' embedded carbon content. Generally, the levy on imported goods 
would be equivalent to the tax applied to domestic goods under a carbon 
tax system. Three legislative bills--H.R. 2069, 110TH Cong. (2007), 
H.R. 3416, 110TH Cong. (2007), and H.R. 1337--111TH Cong. (2009), 
include provisions for a tax on any taxable carbon substance sold by 
the importer. For the purposes of this report, we are using the term 
border tax adjustment to refer to this tax described in the bills and 
to differentiate it from a carbon tax applied to domestic producers. 

Business-as-usual: A scenario in which no action is taken to reduce 
greenhouse gas emissions. 

Cap-and-trade: An emissions pricing system in which the government 
applies an aggregate cap or quota to limit total emissions from 
regulated sources, which are required to hold allowances to cover their 
emissions. Allowances are allocated by the government and may be 
traded. Sources whose allowances exceed their emissions may offer 
permits for sale, while sources for which emissions exceed allowances 
will need to buy them. 

Carbon dioxide equivalent: The quantity of carbon dioxide emissions 
that would trap as much heat as a quantity of non-carbon-dioxide gases, 
such as methane, sulfur hexafluoride, nitrous oxide, or industrial 
gases. 

Carbon leakage: The condition when emissions reductions in one country 
are replaced by increases in emissions in other countries. 

Carbon offsets: Reductions in greenhouse gas emissions from an activity 
in one place to compensate for emissions released elsewhere. 

Carbon tax system: A system that requires regulated sources to pay a 
charge based on the level of their emissions. 

Competitiveness: The ability of a U.S. industry to compete successfully 
in international markets with foreign competitors. 

Cost containment measures: Mechanisms designed to reduce the economic 
impact of climate change legislation on certain regulated entities and 
provide them with flexibility in managing compliance costs. Examples 
include banking and borrowing of allowances, price caps on allowances, 
free allocation of allowances, and carbon offsets. 

Dispute Settlement Body: The WTO's dispute settlement process is 
administered by the Dispute Settlement Body, composed of 
representatives from WTO Members, and rules set time limits for each 
step in the process. 

Downstream regulation: Regulation on sources that emit greenhouse 
gases. 

Embedded carbon content: Carbon emissions associated with the 
production of a product through the entirety of its supply chain. 

Emissions pricing: A market-based mechanism, such as a carbon tax or 
cap-and-trade system, to encourage reductions in emissions by putting a 
price on them. In this report, "emissions pricing" refers to greenhouse 
gas emissions pricing, as opposed to pricing systems for other types of 
emissions. 

Energy intensity: The industry's cost of purchased electricity and fuel 
costs, or energy expenditures, divided by the value of shipments 
(output) of the industry, as defined in H.R. 2454. 

Free allowance allocation: Emission allowances given by the government 
for free. Under a cap-and-trade program governments can either give 
allowances to regulated entities for free or they can sell allowances 
through an auction. Allocating allowances for free represents a 
transfer of wealth from the government to the entities receiving the 
allowances, while auctioning allowances enables the government to 
decide how to use the revenue. 

Greenhouse gas intensity: Twenty times the quantity of carbon dioxide 
equivalent emissions from a sector, divided by the value of shipments 
(output) for the sector, as defined in H.R. 2454. 

Greenhouse gases: Gases such as carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, 
and other substances that increase temperatures by trapping heat that 
would otherwise escape the earth's atmosphere. 

Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC): A scientific 
intergovernmental body set up by the World Meteorological Organization 
(WMO) and by the United Nations Environment Program (UNEP). The IPCC 
was established to provide decision makers and others interested in 
climate change with an objective source of information about climate 
change. 

International reserve allowance: Under a cap-and-trade system, the 
United States could require importers to acquire emissions allowances 
corresponding to the level of greenhouse gases emitted during 
production. 

Output-based rebates: Rebates based on actual, recent measures of 
production that are given to regulated sources in a cap-and-trade 
system for allowances they have purchased to cover their emissions. 

Trade intensity: The ratio of the sum of the value of imports and 
exports within an industry to the sum of the value of shipments 
(output) and imports within an industry, as defined in H.R. 2454. 

Trade measures: Cost equalization measures at the border that impose a 
cost or other requirement on energy-intensive imports from countries 
with weaker climate policies. Depending on the type of domestic carbon 
mitigation system in place, trade measures can take several forms. For 
example, trade measures can be proposed as part of a cap-and-trade 
system (allowance requirement at the border) or a carbon tax system 
(border tax). 

Upstream regulation: Greenhouse gas regulation focused on the sale of 
fuels that produce greenhouse gases when they are used. 

WTO Appellate Body: A body within the WTO's that reviews a WTO panel's 
legal findings during a dispute resolution process. The Appellate Body 
and the Appellate Body's report is to be accepted by parties in the 
dispute unless the Dispute Settlement Body decides by consensus not to 
adopt the report. 

[End of section] 

Footnotes: 

[1] A cap-and-trade system is an emissions pricing system in which the 
government applies an aggregate cap or quota to limit total emissions 
from regulated sources, which are required to hold allowances to cover 
their emissions. Allowances are allocated by the government and may be 
traded. Sources whose allowances exceed their emissions may offer 
permits for sale, while sources for which emissions exceed allowances 
will need to buy them. 

[2] Under a carbon tax system, regulated sources pay a charge based on 
the level of their emissions. 

[3] You also asked GAO to examine revenue measures under consideration 
as part of climate change legislation. GAO plans to issue this product 
later in 2009. 

[4] For example, H.R. 2454 (111th Cong.), and H.R. 1759 (111th 
Congress) include these criteria. HR 2454 also identifies industries 
with an energy intensity of 20 percent or greater as vulnerable to 
adverse competitiveness effects irrespective of trade intensity; 
however, none of the examples we discuss in our analysis would be 
identified as vulnerable under these criteria. 

[5] A study commissioned by energy-intensive industries identifies 41 
manufacturing sub-industries as meeting these vulnerability criteria in 
at least one year between 2004 and 2006, of which 34 sub-industries are 
within primary metals, nonmetallic minerals, paper products, and 
chemicals. We did not conduct sensitivity analysis to determine how 
many additional sub-industries would be identified as vulnerable if the 
criteria were defined more broadly. According to another expert, the 
list of potentially vulnerable sub-industries is greater if using the 
proposed energy-intensive criteria compared with carbon-intensity 
criteria using a per ton carbon price of $20 or $30. Further, 
eliminating the trade-intensity criteria would mean that roughly an 
additional 10 sub-industries would be identified as vulnerable, whereas 
eliminating the energy-intensity criteria would yield over 150 sub-
industries that would be identified as vulnerable to competitiveness 
effects. 

[End of section] 

GAO's Mission: 

The Government Accountability Office, the audit, evaluation and 
investigative arm of Congress, exists to support Congress in meeting 
its constitutional responsibilities and to help improve the performance 
and accountability of the federal government for the American people. 
GAO examines the use of public funds; evaluates federal programs and 
policies; and provides analyses, recommendations, and other assistance 
to help Congress make informed oversight, policy, and funding 
decisions. GAO's commitment to good government is reflected in its core 
values of accountability, integrity, and reliability. 

Obtaining Copies of GAO Reports and Testimony: 

The fastest and easiest way to obtain copies of GAO documents at no 
cost is through GAO's Web site [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov]. Each 
weekday, GAO posts newly released reports, testimony, and 
correspondence on its Web site. To have GAO e-mail you a list of newly 
posted products every afternoon, go to [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov] 
and select "E-mail Updates." 

Order by Phone: 

The price of each GAO publication reflects GAO�s actual cost of
production and distribution and depends on the number of pages in the
publication and whether the publication is printed in color or black and
white. Pricing and ordering information is posted on GAO�s Web site, 
[hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/ordering.htm]. 

Place orders by calling (202) 512-6000, toll free (866) 801-7077, or
TDD (202) 512-2537. 

Orders may be paid for using American Express, Discover Card,
MasterCard, Visa, check, or money order. Call for additional 
information. 

To Report Fraud, Waste, and Abuse in Federal Programs: 

Contact: 

Web site: [hyperlink, http://www.gao.gov/fraudnet/fraudnet.htm]: 
E-mail: fraudnet@gao.gov: 
Automated answering system: (800) 424-5454 or (202) 512-7470: 

Congressional Relations: 

Ralph Dawn, Managing Director, dawnr@gao.gov: 
(202) 512-4400: 
U.S. Government Accountability Office: 
441 G Street NW, Room 7125: 
Washington, D.C. 20548: 

Public Affairs: 

Chuck Young, Managing Director, youngc1@gao.gov: 
(202) 512-4800: 
U.S. Government Accountability Office: 
441 G Street NW, Room 7149: 
Washington, D.C. 20548: