FDIC Home - Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
FDIC - 75 years
FDIC Home - Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation

 
Skip Site Summary Navigation   Home     Deposit Insurance     Consumer Protection     Industry Analysis     Regulations & Examinations     Asset Sales     News & Events     About FDIC  


Home > Industry Analysis > Research & Analysis > FDIC Banking Review




FDIC Banking Review

Troubled Banks: Why Don't They All Fail?
by Robert Oshinsky and Virginia Olin*

A wealth of literature examines the determinants of bank failures and of bank mergers or consolidations. Also numerous are studies that develop failure-prediction models and early-warning systems. But both groups of studies use samples of all banks, and therefore most of this research focuses on pairs of outcomes: failure versus nonfailure, merger versus consolidation,1 or problem bank versus nonproblem bank. But in reality, future status is more than a binary choice.

Here we study only troubled banks—banks that receive a composite CAMELS rating of either 4 or 5 when examined. 2 A focus on troubled banks is valuable to the FDIC and bank researchers for four reasons.   First, when a bank is troubled, failure is but one possible outcome; alternative outcomes are recovery, merger, or continuation as a problem. Second, between 1990 and 2002, 96 percent of all banks that failed had first been troubled banks. Including nonproblem banks would add bias towards non-failure as a possible outcome since a vast majority of nonproblem banks do not fail. Third, if the FDIC can better predict the number of troubled banks that will not fail, it will be better able to estimate the size of its contingent loss reserve. 3 Finally, development of a multistate model identifying financial characteristics that contribute to recovery as well as to failure is important for the FDIC’s long-term strategic planning: accurate predictions of the future states of problem banks would affect the resources applied to these banks.

As noted, troubled banks have four possible outcomes: recovery, merger, continuation as a problem, and failure. Knowing the future states of banks in our sample,4 we construct a financial profile using pre-examination data for the banks grouped by their future state and then use these profiles to develop a multinomial logit estimating procedure that predicts a bank’s likely future state.   We show that a four-state model predicts failure at least as well as binary failure-prediction models and, in addition, provides predictive ability for three alternative future states.

The next section describes previous empirical studies of bank failures, mergers, and financial distress. The three subsequent sections discuss the methodology we use, the sample and data, and the results. The concluding section gives a brief summary.

Empirical Studies

Most of the numerous studies that examine the determinants of bank failures and bank mergers and consolidations, like most of the numerous studies that develop early-warning systems predicting deterioration in banks’ financial condition, construct financial ratios based on information in the Consolidated Reports of Condition and Income (Call Reports) that banks file quarterly with the FDIC. 5 The idea is to construct financial ratios that closely resemble the CAMELS rating system used by bank examiners and to use the ratios to predict pairs of outcomes: failure versus nonfailure, merger versus consolidation, or problem bank versus nonproblem bank. 6 While the information used by examiners is preferable, it is not available without an examination, unlike Call Report data, which are readily available quarterly.

Only a few studies have extended this research beyond pairs of outcomes. In an effort to improve predictive accuracy, DeYoung estimates the long-run probability of failure and acquisition in de novo banks by defining three states: failure, merger by acquisition, and conversion of a whole-bank affiliate of a bank holding company to a branch bank of that same bank holding company.
Wheelock and Wilson use a competing-risks model to consider the joint determination of the probability of being acquired, failing, or surviving. Hannan and Rhoades predict that a bank may experience one of three outcomes: not be acquired, be acquired by a firm operating within the bank’s market, or be acquired by a firm operating outside the bank’s market. 7 DeYoung expects that including the other two exit states (merger by acquisition, and conversion) will make the failure estimates more accurate. Wheelock and Wilson find that inefficiency increases the risk of failure while reducing the probability of a bank’s being acquired. And Hannan and Rhoades find that adding the third state (distinguishing between types of mergers) yields a number of firm and market characteristics that earlier studies did not yield and that significantly influence the likelihood of acquisition.

Rarely in life are the possible outcomes binary. While studies that examine two-state outcomes have benefit, much is lost by not studying other possible outcomes. Further, by limiting our universe to only problem banks, we are able to remove the inherent bias towards the prediction of non-failure status.  

Methodology

Referencing previous studies, we select certain financial variables proven in binary models to be useful in determining future bank state. In our multistate model we use univariate trend analysis to determine whether prior-period financial characteristics differ by future bank state.

Specifically, in the existing literature on bank performance the reasons suggested for failure include low capital, risky asset portfolios, poor management, low earnings, and low liquidity. Thus, the financial variables we select are from those same broad categories: capital adequacy, asset quality, management, earnings, and liquidity. In addition, we run a one-way analysis of variance to examine the financial characteristics of recovered banks versus banks in the other three states (merged or acquired, remained a problem, and failed).

We use a multinomial logistic estimating procedure to model future bank state. Outcomes are nominal, and therefore the multinomial logit model’s assumptions are the closest fit to the specification of the model being estimated. This model simultaneously estimates three binary logits for pairwise comparisons among the outcome categories to a reference outcome.   These binary logits are (1) recover relative to failure, (2) merge relative to failure, and (3) remain a problem relative to failure.

A general form of the model tested is shown in equation 1, where Probability of State (k)i,t is the probability that bank i will be in state k at time t.

(1) Probability of State (k)i,t = F(Financial conditioni,t-1, Economic conditionst )

We gauge the model’s effectiveness in several ways. First, we compare the out-of-sample forecasting accuracy for each of the four states with the actual number of banks ending up in each state.   We compare two competing binary models with the multistate model for failure predictions: one of the two competing models uses the same variables that our multistate model uses, and the other uses the same explanatory variables that Jarrow et al. use, referred to as the loss-distribution model. 8 These two comparisons allow us to test whether including additional alternative states improves the accuracy of failure estimates over the accuracy of binary models. Second, we investigate the economic and statistical effect of our explanatory variables. Third, we check to determine that the banks with the highest predicted probability of failure from our model are the ones that actually fail.

Sample and Data

Our sample consists of 1,996 banks on the FDIC problem-bank list from 1990 through 2002. Each bank has at least one first event and second event that are paired as an observation.   The first event occurs when a bank is examined and receives a CAMELS rating of 4 or 5. The second event occurs when the bank does one of the following: recovers (improves to a CAMELS rating of 1, 2, or 3 at the next examination), merges (either merges with a bank outside of its multibank holding company or consolidates within its multibank holding company),9 remains a problem bank (continues to have a CAMELS rating of 4 or 5 at the next examination), or fails. 10 We use only observations in which first events are paired with second events that occurred 6 to 24 months after the first events. Any second events sooner than 6 months or later than 24 months are ignored, and the observation is dropped from the sample. The reason for this restriction is twofold: first, we want to allow enough time to pass for changes in financial condition to occur; second, during most of our period, all banks except those with assets under $250 million and a composite CAMELS rating of 1 or 2 were required by law to receive safety-and-soundness examinations annually. 11 As noted above, a pairing of events is considered one observation in our sample. Our sample consists of 3,747 observations.

To control implicitly for the effects of economic conditions and banking legislation, we divide these 3,747 observations into annual cohorts corresponding to the year of the first event. But because second events usually occur in a different year from the first events, we recognize that using annual cohorts does not completely control for these effects.

A bank appears as an observation in a cohort only once, and each observation belongs to only one cohort. 12 All observations end with the occurrence of the second event. If the bank in a given cohort reaches the second event as recovered (or merged, or a continued problem), the outcome for the observation for that bank in the cohort is considered a recovery (or a merger, or continuation as a problem).

The same bank can be an observation in multiple cohorts depending on when it first receives a CAMELS rating of 4 or 5 and on its outcome at the second event.   If, at the second event, the bank upon reexamination continues as a problem bank, the first observation ends with an outcome of continuation as a problem bank, and concurrently a second observation for that bank begins and is paired with its corresponding subsequent event, which takes place 6 to 24 months later. At this subsequent event, an outcome is determined for that second observation. In contrast, when a bank’s first observation ends with a second event of recovery or merger, the bank has no concurrent second observation since it is no longer a problem bank. However, recovered banks may reemerge in our sample in a later cohort (for example, the bank recovers but later reverts to problem-bank status), whereupon the bank would be considered a new observation. Banks cannot appear in cohorts after they fail or merge.

Our sample has the following characteristics: The number of problem banks declines drastically during the 1990s as the banking crisis that began in the mid-1980s and lasted through the early 1990s subsided. As figure 1 shows, the 1991 cohort has the highest number (897) and the 1997 cohort the lowest (62). Figure 2 shows that the 1990 and 1998 cohorts have the highest percentage of problem banks that fail—5 percent—and that in the 1997 and 2002 cohorts, no problem banks fail before the second event. Throughout the period most banks remain a problem at the second event: the range is from a high of 69 percent in the 1990 cohort to a low of 40 percent in the 1997 cohort, with an average of 49 percent. The proportion that merge by the second event is small, ranging from 3 percent in the 1990 cohort to 20 percent in the 1998 cohort.   The proportion that recover by the second event ranges from a low of 23 percent in the 1990 cohort to a high of 53 percent in the 1997 cohort (figure 2). Moreover, for banks that recovered we found that large increases in internal capital injections (as a percentage of average assets) peaked in 1996. For those banks, external capital injections increased sharply from 1994 to 1995 but did not peak until 1999 (figure 3). 13 Figure 4 shows that most banks that remain a problem at the second event ultimately recover. 14

Figure 1 - Number of Trobuled Banks by Cohort [D]

Figure 2 - Cohort Composition of Troubled Banks at Second Event [D]

Figure 3 - External and Internal Capital Injections in Troubled Banks That Recovered [D]

Figure 4 - Number of Troubled Banks That Remain a Problem and Ultimately Recover [D]

Using data from the Call Reports, we calculate beginning and ending event financial ratios for each bank. The beginning event ratios are calculated from the Call Report filed just before the first event and the one filed 12 months previously. 15 Balance-sheet items are averaged for the two reporting periods and taken as a ratio of average assets for the same two periods; income items are summed over the 12-month period and taken as a percentage of average assets for the two periods. Similar calculations are made for the ending event, using the Call Report filed immediately before the second event and the one filed 12 months previously.

We group banks by future state to compare their condition and performance.   We then compare data reported at the ending period with those reported at the beginning. We compute the percentage of banks in each state that showed an increase between the two periods for each of the financial ratios.   Assuming that banks that recover are able to improve net income and net noninterest income more than those that fail, we expect to see that the percentages of banks with increases in such ratios will be greater for banks having a future state of recovery than for banks with a future state of failure. For expense items, we expect the opposite. Assuming that banks that recover shed nonperforming and past-due assets, we expect that the percentages of banks with increases in such assets will be less for banks that recover than for those that fail. We expect that the percentages of banks with increases in volatile liabilities and illiquid assets will be smaller for banks having a future state of recovery than for banks with a future state of failure and that the percentages of banks with increases in capital will be larger for banks that recover than for those that fail. For the various financial ratios, we have no expectations for the ranking of banks that merge or are still a problem except that their increases or decreases will fall between the levels for banks that recover and banks that fail.

For measures of earnings, we compare the percentage of banks in each state that showed increases in net interest income, in net noninterest income, and in provision for loan losses. For measures of risky asset portfolios, we compare the percentage of banks in each state that showed increases in average allowance for loan and lease losses, average loans and leases past due 30–89 days, average loans and leases past due 90 days or more, average nonaccrual loans and leases, and average other real estate owned. For measures of capital adequacy we compare the percentage that showed average risk-based capital and average tangible equity capital; for measures of liquidity, the percentage that showed average volatile liabilities and loans and securities with maturities greater than or equal to five years. And for the management measure, we use the efficiency ratio (noninterest expense as a percentage of net interest income plus noninterest income). A lower efficiency ratio is better.

To model future bank states, we selected almost the same financial variables that we used in the univariate trend analysis. 16 For measures of the economy, we added capital injections from a bank holding company and capital injections from outside. 17   From the univariate trend analysis we are able to form expectations about the sign that coefficients on these variables will take when they are estimated by logit analysis. A negative coefficient implies that an increase in the variable will result in the future state’s becoming less likely relative to failure. A positive coefficient implies the opposite.

Table 1 shows the expected sign of explanatory variables used in the multistate model. The financial ratios associated with not failing are capital, capital injections, allowance for loan losses, interest income, noninterest income, and longer-term assets (assets and securities with maturities equal to or great than five years).   Although we expect a negative sign for the efficiency ratio’s coefficient (because lower is better), we associate this ratio, too, with not failing. The financial ratios associated with failure are those measuring poor asset quality (past-due loans, nonaccruing loans, and real estate owned), expense items (interest expense, loss provision, loan charge-offs, salaries, expenses on premises, and other noninterest expense), and volatile liquidity as measured by volatile liabilities. 18

Results

Our results from both the univariate trend analysis and the multistate logit estimating procedure generally agree with expectations. Of banks that recover, the percentage with increases (between the beginning and ending periods) in performance ratios such as net income and net noninterest income is greater than the percentage of banks in any alternative state. For loan-loss provisions, the opposite occurs. In addition, the percentage of banks that have increases in any of the risky asset measures is smaller for banks that recover than for banks in any alternative state. These results can be seen graphically in the appendix.

In the logit analysis, we find that increases in financial ratios associated with nonfailure have positive coefficients, and increases in financial ratios associated with failure have negative coefficients.

Analysis of Variance

Results from the analysis of variance, reported in table 2 and table 3, complement the results of the univariate trend analysis. Both tables use the beginning-period data. Table 2 shows the mean and standard errors for financial variables in each of the four states. Table 3 shows the differences in means and statistical significances for six pairings: (1) recover versus merge, (2) recover versus remain a problem, (3) recover versus fail, (4) remain a problem versus merge, (5) remain a problem versus fail, and (6) merge versus fail.

The results reported in table 2 show that at the first event, the mean value for each financial variable is statistically different from zero. The results also show that the mean values in financial ratios associated with not failing are generally larger for banks that recover, merge, or remain a problem than for banks that fail. The opposite is true for the mean values in financial ratios associated with failing.

There are three exceptions, however: the mean values for total interest income, total noninterest income, and loans and securities with maturities greater than or equal to five years are largest for banks that fail. These results seem counterintuitive until we consider that banks with a future state of fail probably take on riskier assets that will have higher yields than banks with one of the alternative future states.   Or, turning the statement around, we can say that banks with riskier assets have a higher probability of failure.   Fee income from these riskier assets may have resulted in higher noninterest income. And in banks with a future state of fail, the ratio between loans and securities in the longer-term assets may be geared toward loans that are usually considered riskier than more-liquid securities.

The results reported in table 3 show that except for two variables (capital injections from the bank holding company and from outside), the difference in means between banks that recover and those that fail is statistically significant.   Also significant for most variables are the differences in means between banks that fail and both banks that merge and banks that remain a problem.

The results from table 3 indicate as well that the differences in means between banks that remain a problem and both banks that merge and banks that recover are statistically significant. For the recovery-versus-merger pairing, fewer variables are statistically different from one another. And for the pairing remain-a-problem versus merge, even fewer variables are statistically different from one another.

Logit Analysis

For our multivariate analysis, we rely on a multinomial unordered logit probability model that takes into account all four future bank states. Equation 2 shows the model tested:

(2) Probability of State (k)i,t = F(Financial conditioni,t-1 )

For a number of reasons, we did not include variables for economic condition in our model. First, Nuxoll et al. found that state and local economic data did not contribute to the performance of standard off-site models. 19 Second, much of the literature theorizes that the economy is subsumed in the balance sheet, so any effect of the economy will already have shown up in the financial data. 20 Finally, we included capital injections as a proxy for changes in the economy (see footnote 13).

We used a stepwise logit estimation procedure to identify the terms that have a significant relationship in predicting the likelihood that a bank will end up in one of the four states. The stepwise estimation procedure allows us to include several measures of the same attribute in the logit model, yet isolates the most important factors in terms of predicting future bank state.

Table 4 shows summary statistics for the variables used in the logistic regressions.   The beginning-period data, as explained in the section on sample and data, are used in this table. 21   We estimate the logits for each of our cohorts, 1990 through 2002. However, because of the small number of failures after 1993, beginning with the 1994 logit we combine cohorts. The 1994 model is a combination of the 1993 and 1994 cohorts, and the 1995 model combines 1993 through 1995. We continue combining cohorts up to five years (the 1993 through 1997 cohorts for the 1997 logit). For the 1998 through 2002 models, we use a panel of the most recent previous five years.

Table 5, Table 6 and Table 7 show the results. The reference state is failure, so the coefficients are interpreted relative to failure.  As mentioned above, a negative coefficient means that an increase in a variable will have the result that the future state relative to failure becomes less likely.

Eight of the findings are fairly interesting. First, more recent cohorts (beginning with the 1995–1999 cohort) have fewer statistically significant variables than those in the early 1990s.   This result is most likely because of the small number of failures, despite the paneling of data. 22   However, those variables that are statistically significant in the more recent cohorts have the expected sign (as shown in table 1) except for capital injections. For example, in the 1997–2001 cohort, expenses on premises is significant and has a negative sign in table 5 (recovery) and table 7 (still a problem). An increase in this variable will have the result that a future state of either recovery or continuation as a problem becomes less likely relative to failure.

On the other hand, for the cohorts 1994–1998 through 1998–2002, capital injections from outside are significant—but have the unexpected sign both for table 6 (merger) and, in two of those four cohorts, for table 5 (recovery).   Perhaps the negative sign indicates that the institution expects to be acquired and either does not or cannot raise capital. As mentioned in footnote 13, the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act was enacted in 1994.

Second, both the pairing of recovery versus failure (table 5) and the pairing of merger versus failure (table 6) have more statistically significant variables than the pairing of continuation as a problem versus failure (table 7).   We expect that banks that remain a problem more closely resemble banks that fail than they resemble banks that recover or merge. In fact, the univariate trend analysis showed that for most of the financial variables, the percentage of banks that remained a problem was closer to the percentage that failed than were the percentages for the other two future states.

Third, for all cohorts and in each future state, asset-quality variables are statistically significant more often than other variables (table 5, table 6, and table 7). Moreover, the variable nonaccrual loans and leases is more often statistically significant than past-due loans (either 30–89 days or 90 days or more), a result we would expect inasmuch as past-due loans are more likely to improve and be worked out than nonaccrual loans and leases. Further, these asset-quality variables are often negative (as expected from table 1), a sign indicating that an increase in the variable will have the result that the future state relative to failure becomes less likely.

Fourth, surprisingly, tangible equity is highly statistically significant for only the 1990, 1991, and 1992 cohorts in table 5 (recovery) and table 6 (merger).   It is not statistically significant in the remaining years in tables 5 or table 6, nor is it significant in any year in table 7 (continuation as a problem). 23

Fifth, another surprise is in the 1992 cohort, where external capital injections are significant and positive for all three future states (and yet are not significant again until the 1994–1998 cohort for merger [table 6], where the sign is negative).

Sixth, the efficiency ratio is significant only for the 1991 cohort for continuation as a problem versus failure (table 7). Since this ratio uses income and expense variables, we omitted the earnings variables from the model as a robustness check. The results showed that without the earnings variables, the frequency of significance improved in the efficiency ratio. For example, in the 1993–1997 and 1994–1998 cohorts, the efficiency ratio is significant in all three future states and has the expected sign. In the 1991 and 1992 cohorts, it is significant for recovery versus failure and has the expected sign.

Seventh, among the earnings ratios, loan-loss provision is the most consistently significant ratio in all three future states, but more so for recovery (table 5) than for the other two outcomes (table 6 and table 7). This result makes sense since the sooner loan losses are recognized, the more likely it is that a bank will survive. We also tried running the logits without the efficiency ratio to see whether we could gain more significance in the earnings ratios.   However, the significance in the earnings ratios still did not become more frequent.

Finally, the most startling result is in the 1994–1998 cohort for all three future states: the coefficients for loans past due 90 days, nonaccrual loans and leases, and other real estate owned are much larger than in any other cohorts, and the sign on other real estate owned is positive (indicating that an increase in this variable is more likely to result in nonfailure). The likely explanation lies in the small number of failures and the particular nature of the banks in the 1994–1998 cohort. The number of failures fell from 10 in the 1993–1997 cohort to 7 in the 1994–1998 cohort, and one of the failures in 1998 was a bank that failed because of fraudulent activity and therefore had a very low amount of other real estate owned—perhaps low enough to skew the model.   For example, the mean of other real estate owned (as a percentage of assets) for failed banks in the 1993–1997 cohort equaled 3.0 percent; for the 1994–1998 cohort, the mean dropped to 0.62 percent.

Prediction of State: Out-of-Sample Results

The true measure of the logit model’s contribution is its accuracy in making out-of-sample predictions. To test the accuracy, we forecast future bank states using prior-period estimations from our unordered logit model on the following year’s cohort. For example, we use the coefficients from the 1990 cohort to predict the future state of the 1991 cohort, coefficients from the 1991 cohort to predict the future state of the 1992 cohort, and so on. Since our model is estimated from paired observations of first events and outcomes at second events, no observations that are in the 1990 cohort can be in the 1991 cohort (see explanation of observations in the section above on sample and data). To determine all predictions of state, we summed predicted probabilities of state for the cohort, deriving the expected number of banks in each future state.   Figures 5 through 7 show the results.  

Figure 5 - Banks That Recovered [D]

Figure 6 - Banks That Were Acquired [D]

Figure 7 - Banks That Continued as a Problem [D]

All three figures show that the number of banks predicted for each state is very close to the number of banks that actually ended up in the state. For 1996, for example, figure 5 shows that the logit predicts 27 banks to recover, and 26 banks actually recovered; figure 6 shows that 5 banks are predicted to be acquired, compared with 3 that actually were; and figure 7 shows that 26 banks are predicted to remain a problem, compared with 29 that actually did remain a problem.

To test binary forecasts against our multistate model, we do two comparisons.   First, we run a binary model using the same financial variables as in the multistate model to predict failure versus nonfailure. We then compare the predicted probabilities of failure from this binary model with predicted probabilities of failure from the multistate model.

The first comparison is shown in figure 8, which compares the forecasts of the two models with the actual number of failed banks. As can be seen, both models predict failure fairly accurately.   The second comparison is shown in figure 9, which compares the predicted probabilities of failure from our multistate model with predictions from the loss-distribution model (LDM). This model uses variables found in conventional bank-failure literature to predict bank failure within the second quarter after the Call Report is filed. In our test, we use the betas from the LDM estimated one year earlier to predict failures of problem banks for the following year. For example, the LDM predicted that eight banks would fail in 1994 (figure 9). The predictions resulted from the use of the betas estimated in the 1993 LDM.

Figure 8 - Banks That Failed, Multistate and Bivariate Models [D]

Figure 9 - Banks That Failed, Multistate and LDM Models [D]

However, as noted above in the section on sample and data, a second event for an observation may occur as many as 24 months after the first event. A bank on the problem list in December 1993 may be in our 1992 cohort that used Call Report data after 1993 in the estimation.   Thus, to get a true out-of-sample prediction using our model, we have to use the estimated betas from a cohort two years before the date for which we are predicting failures for problem banks.   The prediction that six banks would fail in 1994 resulted from the use of estimated betas from our 1992 model (figure 9). But since the LDM requires only a one-year prediction horizon, one would expect it to be a better predictor of failure than our model. This expectation is not quite borne out. As figure 9 shows, the two models are comparable. The advantage of ours is that we can predict not only problem-bank failure but also problem-bank recovery, merger, and continuation as a problem.

To determine whether banks with the highest probability of failure are the ones that actually fail, we rank banks that our model predicts to fail in each period by their probability of failure. We then divide the predicted failures into deciles to determine whether the highest decile contains the largest number of banks that actually failed.   Of the 65 failed banks in our cohorts from 1991 through 2002, 38 were in the tenth decile. 24 An additional 8 banks were in the ninth decile.

The results for the remaining three states, however, were not quite as accurate.   Of the 1,058 recovered banks in our cohorts from 1991 through 2002, 166 (16 percent) were in the tenth decile; adding the 159 banks in the ninth decile raises the percentage to 31. For banks that are predicted to merge, 14 percent are in the tenth decile (26 banks out of the 191 banks that merged in our cohorts from 1991 through 2002); and for banks that are predicted to remain a problem, 15 percent are in the tenth decile.

Despite the weaker results for the remaining three states, the accuracy in forecasting future bank states is noteworthy. Arguably, this model could be used to predict troubled banks’ future state with decent reliability.

Economic Significance

To test the economic significance of the explanatory variables, we use a fairly standard approach: first we evaluate in-sample predicted state probabilities on the basis of the mean values of explanatory variables, and then we evaluate how these probabilities change with marginal changes in key explanatory variables.   Because asset-quality variables—specifically, loans past due 90 days or more and nonaccrual loans and leases—were the variables most consistently significant across panels, we compared their economic significance in two periods: 1990 and the panel 1995–99.

We use the predicted in-sample state probabilities for 1990 and the 1995–99 panel based on the mean values for explanatory variables in 1990 and in the 1995–99 panel. The means for the sample of banks used in model estimation for both periods are shown in table 8.

The predicted state probabilities evaluated at the mean for banks in the 1990 cohort are 16.41 percent for recover, 1.82 percent for merge, 80.82 percent for remain a problem, and 0.95 percent for fail. Both loans past due 90 days or more and nonaccrual loans and leases were statistically significant in 1990 and in the 1995–99 panel. Table 9 shows the effects on estimated state probabilities, ceteris paribus, should each of these ratios experience a 1 percentage point increase in either of the periods examined. For example, in 1990 the mean for loans past due 90 days or more equaled 0.7964 percent of assets. If that is increased 1 percentage point to 1.7964 percent, the probability of recovery decreases from 16.41 percent to 12.52 percent, the probability of merger decreases from 1.82 percent to 1.59 percent, the probability of continuation as a problem increases from 80.82 percent to 84.74 percent, and the probability of failure increases from 0.95 percent to 1.15 percent.

Summary

We offer an approach that differs from that of previous failure-prediction models by focusing on troubled banks only. As a result, we can estimate a model that predicts failure as well as the three alternative outcomes to failure: recovery, merger, and continuation as a problem. Further, this model predicts failure as successfully as the standard binary failure-prediction model.

For the deposit insurer, this four-state model offers more information about the possible future states of problem banks than a two-state model can.   This additional information can better assist the FDIC in long-term strategic planning regarding problem banks.   This planning involves budgeting personnel, time, and funding.    Moreover, our model shows that certain explanatory variables affect future bank state.   This knowledge may help regulators choose policies that affect the likelihood that troubled banks can successfully resolve their own problems.

REFERENCES

Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli. 1989.   Deposit-Institution Failures: A Review of the Empirical Literature. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review (Quarter 4): 2–18.

DeYoung, Robert. 2003.   De Novo Bank Exit. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 35, no. 5:711–28.

Cole, Rebel A., and Jeffery W. Gunther. 1998. Predicting Bank Failures: A Comparison of On- and Off-Site Monitoring Systems. Journal of Financial Services Research 13, no. 2:103–17.

Gunther, Jeffery W., and Robert R. Moore. 2000. Financial Statements and Reality: Do Troubled Banks Tell All? Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic and Financial Review (Quarter 3): 30–35.

Hannan, Timothy H., and Stephen A. Rhoades. 1987. Acquisition Targets and Motives: The Case of the Banking Industry. Review of Economics and Statistics 69, no. 1:67–74.

Jagtiani, Julapa, James Kolari, Catharine Lemieux, and Hwan Shin.   2003. Early Warning Models for Bank Supervision: Simpler Could Be Better.   Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives (Quarter 3): 49–60.

Jarrow, Robert A., Rosalind L. Bennett, Michael C. Fu, Daniel A. Nuxoll, and Huiju Zhang. 2003.   A General Martingale Approach to Measuring and Valuing the Risk to the FDIC Deposit Insurance Funds. Unpublished paper, presented at the FDIC Conference on Finance and Banking: New Perspectives.

Jones, Kenneth D., and Tim Critchfield. 2004. The Declining Number of U. S. Banking Organizations: Will the Trend Continue? Future of Banking Study.   FDIC. Online. Available at http://www.fdic. gov/bank/analytical/future/index.html [March 11, 2005].

King, Thomas B., Andrew P. Meyer, Daniel A. Nuxoll, and Timothy J. Yeager.   2005. Are the Causes of Bank Distress Changing? Can Researchers Keep Up? Center for Financial Research Working Paper Series, no. 2005-03. FDIC.

Kolari, James, Dennis Glennon, Hwan Shin, and Michele Caputo. 2002. Predicting Large U. S. Commercial Bank Failures. Journal of Economic and Business 54:361–87.

Nuxoll, Daniel A., John O’Keefe, and Katherine Samolyk. 2003. Do Local Economic Data Improve Off-Site Bank-Monitoring Models? FDIC Banking Review 15, no. 2:39–53.

Whalen, Gary. 1991.   A Proportional Hazard Model of Bank Failure: An Examination of Its Usefulness as an Early Warning Tool.   Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review 27, no. 1:21–31.

Wheelock, David C., and Paul W. Wilson. 2000. Why do Banks Disappear? The Determinants of U. S. Bank Failures and Acquisitions. Review of Economics and Statistics 82, no. 1:127–38.

APPENDIX

Figure A1 - Increases in Net Interest Income [D]

Figure A2 - Increases in Net Noninterest Income [D]

Figure A3 - Increases in Loss Provision [D]

Figure A4 - Increases in Loan-Loss Reserves [D]

Figure A5 - Increases in Loans 30-89 Days Past Due [D]

Figure A6 - Increases in Loans 90 Days or More Past Due [D]

Figure A7 - Increases in Nonaccrual Loans [D]

Figure A8 - Increases in Other Real Estate Owned [D]

Figure A9 - Increases in Risk-Based Capital [D]

Figure A10 - Increases in Tangible Capital [D]

Figure A11 - Increases in Volatile Liabilities [D]

Figure A12 - Increases in Increases in Loans and Securities with Maturities Greater than or Equal to Five Years [D]

Figure A13 - Increases in the Efficiency Ratio [D]

FOOTNOTES

* Robert Oshinsky is a Senior Financial Economist and Virginia Olin is a former Senior Financial Economist, Division of Insurance and Research, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). The authors thank John O'Keefe for his overall guidance; Andrew Davenport for his counsel; and Jesse Weiher, Brian Lamm, James Marino, and the anonymous readers of the FDIC for their careful review of the article and their valuable comments and suggestions. The authors also thank Robert DeYoung for his suggestions. Of course, all mistakes are the responsibility of the authors. The views expressed here are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the FDIC.

1 In previous studies, a merger is the absorption of a bank by a previously unrelated bank while consolidation is the absorption of a bank by a related bank. For purposes of this paper, we combine the two types of absorptions and refer to them as mergers.

2 Because of the nature of the resolution process, we deliberately omit troubled thrifts, including those resolved by the Resolution Trust Corporation, which kept insolvent thrifts open during the resolution process. CAMELS is an acronym for the six components of the regulatory rating system: Capital adequacy, Asset quality, Management, Earnings, Liquidity, and (since 1998) market Sensitivity. Banks are rated from 1 (the best) to 5 (the worst), and banks with a composite rating of 4 or 5 are considered problem banks. A rating of 4 generally indicates that the bank exhibits unsafe or unsound practices or is in an unsafe or unsound condition, while a rating of 5 means that the bank's practices or condition are extremely unsafe or unsound.

3 The mission of the FDIC is to protect depositors and promote the safety and soundness of insured depository institutions and the U. S. financial system by identifying, monitoring, and addressing risks to the deposit insurance funds. The FDIC's Financial Risk Committee quantifies risks to the deposit insurance system for purposes of financial reporting and fund management, and each quarter it meets to set a contingent loss reserve estimated from total assets of banks that may fail within two years.

4 Our sample consists of institutions assigned a CAMELS rating of 4 and 5 between 1990 and 2002. The sample is described in detail in a later section of this article.

5 For reviews of the literature, see Demirgüç-Kunt (1989), Jagtiani et al. (2003), and King et al. (2005).

6 See Whalen (1991), Cole and Gunther (1998), Kolari et al. (2002), and Jagtiani et al. (2003).

7 DeYoung (2003), Wheelock and Wilson (2000), and Hannan and Rhoades (1987).

8 Jarrow et al. (2003).

9 We recognize that mergers and consolidations have different characteristics. However, during the period we study, the number of consolidations is small (39), so we combined both events into one state.

10 Here we define failure either as a closing that results from an action by a regulator or as a merger assisted by the FDIC.

11 The frequency of examinations was set by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991 (FDICIA). Further exceptions to the requirement for annual safety-and-soundness exams are listed in the act.

12 Technically a bank may appear as a second observation in the same cohort since the window for the second event is as short as six months.

13 Jones and Critchfield (2004) note three reasons that might explain the 1997 and 1998 peak years for merger activity and recoveries: (1) banks were highly profitable, liquid, and operating in favorable economic and interest-rate environments; (2) in 1994 the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act removed the remaining barriers to interstate banking and branching; and (3) a record-breaking bull market in stocks pushed market valuations of banks and thrifts to unprecedented levels, encouraging many banking firms to use their stock as currency to purchase other firms.

14 The reason for the decline beginning in 2001 in the percentage of still-a-problem banks that ultimately recover is that enough follow-up events have not yet occurred. Most banks remain a problem beyond a second event.

15 Gunther and Moore (2000) find atypical movements in Call Report data for the quarters in which banks are downgraded by examiners. These Call Reports are more subject to revisions. For that reason, we also did our univariate analysis on the Call Reports filed before the ones specified in this article. The resulting trends in data were similar to the trends reported here.

16 For the logits we used total income and detailed expense items instead of net interest and net noninterest income as used in the univariate analysis. In addition, we also estimated the model using Call Report data from the quarter before the quarter that precedes the examination, as in the univariate. The results differed little from those reported here.

17 As pointed out in footnote 13, the economy (a record-breaking bull market) was one reason noted for increased acquisitions.

18 Volatile liabilities are defined in the FDIC data dictionary as (1) federal funds purchased and sold under agreements to repurchase, (2) demand notes issued to the U. S. Treasury and other borrowed money, (3) time deposits over $100,000 held in domestic offices, (4) foreign-office deposits, (5) trading liabilities less trading liabilities' revaluation losses on interest rate, (6) foreign exchange rate, and (7) other commodity and equity contracts.

19 Nuxoll et al. (2003).

20 As a robustness check, we estimated the model using three variables for the United States economy: a ratio of the number of problem banks to total number of banks by state, a ratio of the assets of problem banks to total assets by state, and the percentage change in state housing permits. The first test was an estimation using only the economic variables as explanatory variables. We did two estimations: one used the ratio of the number of problem banks to total number by state and the percentage change in state housing permits; the second used the ratio of the assets of problem banks to total assets by state and the percentage change in housing permits. These variables were significant for most of these estimations. However, when these variables were included in estimations with the rest of the explanatory variables, their significance disappeared.

21 As with the univariate analysis, we also ran the logits using a beginning period one quarter before the quarters specified previously. The results revealed little difference.

22 From the 1995-1999 cohort through the 1998-2002 cohort, the number of failures totaled 7, 7, 8, and 8, respectively, compared with 45, 36, and 17 for the cohorts 1990 through 1992.

23 Thinking that tangible equity would be correlated with capital injections, we ran the models using only tangible equity. However, taking out capital injections made no difference in significance.

24 For the binary model, 39 of the 65 failed banks were in the tenth decile.




Last Updated 3/31/2006 Questions, Suggestions & Requests

Home    Contact Us    Search    Help    SiteMap    Forms
Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) Service Center    Website Policies    USA.gov
FDIC Office of Inspector General