THE TIMBER HILL GROUP
TWO PICKWICK PLAZA
GREENWICH, CONNECTICUT
(203) 618-5801

David M. Battan
Vice President and General Counsel
Interactive Brokers LLC

November 16, 1999

VIA HAND DELIVERY

Jonathan G. Katz, Secretary
Securities and Exchange Commission
450 Fifth Street, N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20549

Re: Application for Registration as a National Securities Exchange

Filed by International Securities Exchange, File No. 10-127

Dear Mr. Katz:

The Timber Hill Group, respectfully submits these comments on the amendment filed by the International Securities Exchange ("ISE") to its application to register as a national securities exchange. ISE's application should not be approved unless certain preferential, anti-competitive rules -- particularly ISE's unprecedented rule against electronic creation and transmission of non-market maker orders -- are eliminated or amended to comply with the Commission's vision of an open, accessible and transparent national options market.

The most dangerous of these rules is Rule 717(f), which to our knowledge represents the first time on any exchange that customers and ordinary exchange members would be prohibited from placing orders that are created and transmitted electronically. Likewise, ISE's prohibition against transmission of two-sided orders by Electronic Access Members ("EAMs"), and its trade or fade rule will, if approved, create a two-tiered market that will benefit privileged classes of exchange members at the expense of public customers who will be denied access to better, more accurate prices. The ISE has not provided the Commission with any evidence that these anti-competitive preferences are necessary or are the least restrictive means to protect the public interest. See National Securities Markets Improvement Act of 1996 ยง 106; H.R. Rep. No. 104-622 (June 17, 1996)(requiring "rigorous analysis" of competitive impact of proposed rules, including "specific analysis of costs and benefits").

Indeed, the troubling argument offered by the ISE in support of most of these corrosive rules is that they are necessary because some existing options exchanges have similar rules. Even if trade or fade rules or prohibitions on competitive two-sided orders may have had some justification on open outcry floors before the advent of modern trading technology, they have no place on the technology-driven exchanges of the future. Thus, Timber Hill urges the Commission to work with the ISE to revise or eliminate preferential and anti-competitive rules and to do likewise with the other options exchanges as the Commission moves forward over the next several months. In the words of Chairman Levitt:

"We cannot forget that it is the interests of investors that ultimately must guide the Commission's actions, not the interests of individual market centers or their participants.Any rules or practices that place the interests of intermediaries ahead of those of investors should not be part of the future of the securities markets."

Specific Comments

The most serious barrier to open and fair competition on the ISE, and an extremely dangerous precedent for the securities markets as a whole, is Rule 717(f), which states:

"Members may not enter, nor permit the entry of, orders created and communicated electronically without manual input (i.e., order entry by Public Customers or associated persons of Members must involve manual input such as entering the terms of an order into an order-entry screen or manually selecting a displayed order against which an off-setting order should be sent)."

To the best of our knowledge, ISE Rule 717(b) is the only rule of its kind on any options or other derivatives exchange anywhere in the world. It is remarkable on many levels:

ISE is bracingly honest about the motivation for the rule: "fear that automatic order-generation systems will hit [market maker] quotes . . . before the market makers' own automatic quotation system is able to react to a change in the underlying price." In other words, customers and EAMs are denied the opportunity to use any technology that might result in faster, better prices than those of the market makers. In light of some of the regrettable past practices of the options exchanges, this is noteworthy.

A publicly chartered national securities exchange is not intended to be a casino, where players know they will lose money in the long run because the house builds the slot machines. Options exchanges have a unique public purpose in providing a forum for hedging and discovery of future prices for the underlying securities. The sophisticated participants in these markets - both customers and members -- depend on lightning-fast markets that adjust to changes in the value of the underlying instruments as rapidly as possible so that prices are accurate and hedges are precise. Market makers should be expected to have highly advanced systems based on sophisticated pricing models that generate fast, accurate prices for users of these critical markets. If they do not, and a sophisticated customer or EAM has a better, faster price, it would severely disservice the public interest to prevent that price from being posted, simply to guarantee a profit for the market maker.

As discussed above, the Commission and the Congress have been urging the deployment of advanced technology in the securities industry for decades. As early as 1975, Congress noted:

"The linking of all markets for qualified securities through communication and data processing facilities will foster efficiency, enhance competition, increase the information available to brokers, dealers, and investors, facilitate the offsetting of investors' orders, and contribute to best execution of such orders."

The Commission repeatedly has stressed this theme, most recently in speeches and Congressional testimony by the Chairman and the Commissioners:

"Advancing technology and innovation do not allow us the luxury of standing still. Although the landscape of tomorrow's markets may not resemble today's, the fundamental Exchange Act objective that will guide the Commission - a national market system characterized by transparency, competition, and linkages - remains the same."

If ISE is allowed to prevent customers and public members from using any technology that might improve prices of the market makers, other exchanges surely would follow and customers and the public would pay the price in perpetuity. This is not where our markets should be heading.

Under the National Securities Market Improvement Act the Commission must rigorously "analyze the potential costs and benefits of any rulemaking initiative." ISE's one-paragraph attempt to justify its ban on electronic creation and transmission of orders is unsupported by a single shred of data, and provides the Commission no evidentiary foundation upon which to approve the rule.

* * * *

II. Other Anti-Competitive Rules

A. Limitation on Entry of Two-Sided Orders by Electronic Access Members

Another serious barrier to open and fair competition on the ISE is proposed rule 717(b), which prohibits ordinary ISE members (EAMs) from entering two-sided limit orders into ISE's system, either as principal or agent, on a regular or continuous basis. The clear purpose of this rule is to prevent outsiders from posting bids and offers that might equal or better those of the ISE-designated PMMs and CMMs and that would narrow spreads and lower the volume of transactions that these privileged members capture. However effective the rule might be in protecting favored exchange members, it is flatly inconsistent with the fundamental purpose of the markets: to provide the most liquidity to the investing public at the lowest possible cost.

The prohibition against EAMs submitting two-sided limit orders on a regular or continuous basis is reminiscent of similar rules established as part of pilot programs at the Chicago Board Options Exchange and the Pacific Exchange -- under which brokers using hand-held terminals in certain trading crowds are prohibited from using those terminals to enter two-sided limit orders. See Exchange Act Release 34-38054, 61 Fed. Reg. 67365 (Dec. 20, 1996)(approving CBOE pilot program prohibiting, in one options class, use of hand-held terminals to enter two-sided orders because exchange claimed off-floor market making would entice market makers to leave the floor); Exchange Act Release 34-39970, 67 SEC Docket 211 (May 7, 1998)(approving Pacific Exchange pilot program prohibition on same grounds).

In a floor-based environment, these rules restricting so-called "upstairs" market making had at least an arguable rationale sufficient to justify their implementation on a trial basis, although we understand that the Department of Justice is investigating these restrictions as part of its inquiry into competitive practices on the options exchanges. In any event, ISE's graft of this anti-competitive rule from the pen-and-ink environment to the electronic trading arena - where everyone is "upstairs" is not supportable and will lead inevitably to less competition and wider trading spreads.

The only justification offered by ISE for stifling price and volume competition is that protective measures are necessary to entice firms to become CMMs and PMMs so that they will provide liquidity to the exchange in difficult markets. However, as the Commission has noted recently, global computing and telecommunications systems are eliminating the inefficiencies of the past and bringing pools of liquidity together in ways that were inconceivable in the floor-based trading world. Likewise, European derivatives exchanges have proven that when customers and broker-dealers have open and fair access to exchange electronic trading systems from around the globe, there is sufficient liquidity to maintain orderly markets without paying a privileged few for the mostly theoretical obligation to be steadfast in rough markets.

The ISE has not made the required showing under the National Securities Market Improvement Act that maintaining artificially high spreads by excluding outside two-sided orders is the least restrictive and anti-competitive method of assuring sufficient liquidity on the exchange. As we noted in our initial comment letter, even without Rule 717(b)'s ban of outside market making, PMMs and CMMs are given plenty of generous incentives to participate in the ISE, including the right to participate in all trades within an options group that exceed a minimum size, and a limitation on the number of CMM memberships. Moreover, there is no evidence that providing PMMs and CMMs with artificial freedom from competition in favorable conditions will encourage them to act fairly or not use this same artificial advantage in unfavorable conditions. Especially in light of the Commission's recent concerns about best execution and price improvement, access to new markets "should not be frustrated by unreasonable fees or other barriers that have an anticompetitive effect."

B. ISE's Trade or Fade Rule

Our final objection relates to the ISE's proposed trade-or-fade rule, which ISE retained in its amended application notwithstanding negative commentary. For the reasons explained at length in our initial comment letter, "trade or fade" is a concept whose time has long passed. By authorizing a market maker or trading crowd to refuse to honor its quotes if the prospective counterparty is a broker-dealer, trade or fade rules distort the exchange pricing mechanism and undermine the integrity of the marketplace. ISE seems to agree with this, calling trade or fade rules "unfortunate" and "troublesome" but defending its trade or fade rule on the ground that the other exchanges do it.

When the options exchanges first proposed their "trade or fade" rules to the Commission, they jointly represented that the rules were necessary to minimize "trade-throughs" in multiply listed options. A trade-through occurs when an order is filled at one exchange at a price that is inferior to the price available elsewhere. According to the exchanges, trade-throughs were occurring not because better prices were in fact available at another exchange, but merely because the competing exchange had allowed its disseminated quotes to grow stale. Trade or fade rules were offered as the solution to this problem.

Again, trade or fade rules might have made sense in the time before advanced computing technology became widely available and updating prices was not automated. In today's world, however, it is difficult to see any justification for trade or fade. If specialists and market makers - who are compensated highly for the obligation to post accurate two-sided markets - are posting stale or bait-and-switch quotes, the solution is not to allow them to disavow those quotes but to make them honor them. We suspect that the problem of stale quotes and trade-throughs would disappear very quickly if specialists and market makers were held firm to all their quotes.

In any event we hope that this issue is moot. On October 19, 1999, the Commission ordered the exchanges to propose a plan to create a linkage arrangement that would prevent trade-throughs. The Commission further noted:

"As part of the implementation of trade-through rules, the Options Exchanges should submit to the Commission proposed rule changes repealing existing trade or fade rules that become unnecessary with the adoption of trade-through rules."

In light of the Commission's rightful desire to eliminate exchange trade or fade rules, it is self-evident that the Commission should disallow ISE's Rule 804(d)(2).

Conclusion

We urge the Commission to consider the ISE rules discussed above in the context of the Commission's vision for the open, fair and transparent exchanges of the future. The negative impact of exchange rules creating preferences for a limited class of exchange insiders at the expense of others is felt not only by outside members who are prevented from competing on a level playing field, but by public customers who pay the hidden costs of higher bid ask spreads and less accurate prices because of barriers to competition.

Sincerely,

David M. Battan

Vice President and General Counsel
Interactive Brokers LLC

cc: Hon. Arthur Levitt
Hon. Isaac C. Hunt, Jr.
Hon. Norman Johnson
Hon. Paul R. Carey
Hon. Laura Simone Unger
Annette L. Nazareth, Esq.
Sheila Slevin, Esq.
Christine Richardson, Esq.
Joseph Morra, Esq.