USDA Economic Research Service Briefing Room
" "  
Link: Bypass USDA Left navigation.
Search ERS

Browse by Subject
Diet, Health & Safety
Farm Economy
Farm Practices & Management
Food & Nutrition Assistance
Food Sector
Natural Resources & Environment
Policy Topics
Research & Productivity
Rural Economy
Trade and International Markets
Also Browse By


or

""

 


 
Briefing Rooms

India: Policy

Contents
 

Agricultural Policy
Agricultural Trade Policy
Domestic Agricultural Market Regulation and Investment
More Information

Agricultural Policy

Since it gained independence, India has pursued a policy of food self-sufficiency, primarily by boosting domestic production of its major food staples: rice and wheat. This basic goal has been achieved by developing and adopting high-yielding varieties, expanding irrigation, and increasing fertilizer use—all aided by supportive output price and input subsidy policies. Cropped area has also increased steadily as expansion in irrigation has boosted multiple cropping and cropping intensity.

Policies and performance for other crops have been mixed. For pulses (chickpeas, pigeon peas, lentils, dry peas, etc.), an important protein source in Indian diets, there has been little success in boosting output, and India has pursued a liberal import policy since the early 1980s. In the oilseed sector, generally high levels of protection for oilseeds and edible oils have not yielded major gains in output. As a result, India is now among the world's largest importers of edible oils, while Indian consumers pay among the highest prices in the world. For cotton, the widespread adoption of hybrid Bt cotton—so far, the only genetically modified crop approved for cultivation in India—has led to rapid growth in output since the early 2000s, supporting expansion of both raw cotton and textile product exports. With rising incomes diversifying food demand, nonstaple foods—including fruits, vegetables, dairy products, eggs, and meats—are now experiencing the fastest growth in production and consumption, but with relatively little policy intervention in either input or output markets.

India's major policy instruments for domestic agriculture include minimum support prices (MSPs)for major crops; input subsidies for fertilizer, power, and irrigation water; and a public distribution system that provides subsidized food staples—primarily wheat and rice—to food-insecure segments of the population. MSPs are set annually and, if necessary, defended through market procurement by central and state government agencies. Historically, MSP policy for food staples has balanced producer incentives with the need to maintain consumer price stability, but recent adjustments to MSPs suggest a significant shift toward stronger grower incentives.

Real minimum support prices for major Indian crops 1/

Outlays for input subsidies for fertilizers, electrical power used for agriculture, and irrigation water distributed through surface irrigation systems increased about 6 percent annually in real terms (adjusted for inflation) between fiscal years 1993/94 (April-March) and 2005/06, when input subsidies totaled about 530 billion rupees (US$11.9 billion). The cost of providing subsidized electricity for agriculture accounted for about 30 percent of total agricultural input subsidies in 2005/06. Fertilizer subsidies are provided both to farmers in the form of price subsidies for domestic and imported fertilizers, and to the fertilizer industry in the form of preferential prices to offset the losses of higher cost plants. Irrigation subsidies cover the operational costs of providing surface water irrigation that are not recovered from users.

India's agricultural input subsidies

Since 2005/06, the cost of input subsidies has increased sharply, primarily because of the rising prices for domestic and imported fertilizer feedstocks that have not been passed on to farmers. Since 2005/06, the cost of the fertilizer subsidy has increased more than fivefold, reaching an estimated Rs1.0 trillion ($22 billion) in 2008/09.

The budgetary costs of operating India's system of MSPs, public distribution, and storage for wheat and rice are accounted for in the "food grain subsidy." The real cost of the food grain subsidy increased sharply in the late 1990s, when India accumulated large surpluses of wheat and rice in government stocks. The subsidy declined as stocks were reduced in the early 2000s but is now poised to rise again as a result of rent increases in minimum support prices, unchanged subsidized issue prices for low-income consumers through the Public Distribution System, and the likelihood of higher government stockholding costs. Overall, the real cost of the food grain subsidy has increased about 9 percent annually since the early 1990s, and is expected to reach a record of Rs360 billion ($8 billion) in 2008/09.

India's food grain subsidy 1/

Stronger economic growth since the major industrial and trade policy reforms of 1991-93 and slowed farm sector investment and growth (see the Basic Information chapter for more detail) are creating pressure for change in India's agricultural policies. Food demand is expanding, diversifying, and placing new demands on underdeveloped agricultural markets and institutions. Longstanding production, procurement, and distribution programs that focus on cereals are increasingly expensive and out of step with market demand. At the same time, rising subsidy outlays appear to be constraining public investment in transforming institutions and market infrastructure, while private investment in agriculture and agribusiness has been limited, in part due to national and state level regulatory interventions in agricultural markets. Although the central government plays an important role in recommending national agricultural policies and is the primary source of funds, agriculture is a "state subject" in the Indian constitution. As a result, all agricultural policies—including price supports, input subsidies, produce marketing, and consumer subsidies—must ultimately be formally adopted and implemented by state governments. The support of India's various states, which reflect a broad range of interests and resource endowments, is a key issue in reaching consensus on agricultural policy and in implementing policy change.

There have been some important changes in agricultural policy since the early 1990s, including the removal of quantitative trade restrictions completed in 2001, steps to reform state regulations that impeded private investment in agricultural markets, implementation of a unified value-added tax structure across Indian states, adoption of a new unified "Food Law" that will simplify food processing and trade, and large increases in the availability of credit for agricultural producers and agribusinesses. The poor performance of the rural sector was a key issue in the last round of national elections in 2004 and will likely remain an issue in the upcoming 2009 elections and beyond.

Top of page

Agricultural Trade Policy

From the time it gained independence in 1947 until the early 1990s, India maintained firm control over imports and exports of both agricultural and nonagricultural goods, making it one of the most closed economies in the world. During this period, India's domestic markets were insulated from world markets by various restrictive practices, including trade bans, licensing regimes, state trading, and other quantitative restrictions, as well as high tariffs. Fundamental reform of domestic and trade policies affecting the industrial and service sectors began during 1991-93, when many restrictive licensing arrangements and quantitative restrictions were lifted and basic tariffs were substantially reduced.

While quantitative restrictions on imports of some agricultural commodities, most notably pulses and edible oils, were freed up in the 1980s and 1990s, the general removal of quantitative restrictions on agricultural trade occurred following the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture (AoA). The AoA required India to bind agricultural tariffs at ceiling rates ranging from 0 to 100 percent for primary products, 150 percent for processed products, and 300 percent for edible oils. In 1997, when India lost the balance-of-payments waiver that allowed it to maintain restrictive trade policies, India accelerated the process of lifting quantitative import restrictions (QRs). India completed the removal of QRs in April 2001, and nearly all agricultural products can now be imported subject to a tariff and to sanitary and phytosanitary standards.

While India's bound agricultural tariffs are among the highest in the world, applied tariffs for many products are set well below bound rates. India's policy has been to adjust applied tariffs periodically to help meet domestic price stability goals; either raising tariffs to help strengthen producer prices or reducing tariffs to help moderate rising consumer prices. In 2007 and 2008, India reduced tariffs for a number of major commodities—in many cases to zero—to help curb inflationary pressures and moderate the impact of high world prices on the domestic market. In general, however, tariffs have significant impacts on domestic prices of only the few agricultural commodities that India trades regularly in large volumes, such as edible oils and pulses. For most agricultural commodities, Indian domestic prices are below transport-adjusted world prices.

India's bound and applied tariffs for selected agricultural products
Commodity
Bound tariff
rate
Applied tariff rate
August 2007 November 2008
   
Percent
 
Imported products:

Pulses

100
10
0
Wheat
100
0
0
Onions
100
5
5
Crude soybean oil
45
40
20
Refined soybean oil
45
45
7.5
RBD palm olein 1/
300
52.5
7.5
Other products:
Atta
150
0
0
Corn
70
0
0
Rice
70
70
0
Oilseeds
100
30
30
1/ RBD = Refined, bleached, and deodorized.
Source: Government of India, Ministry of Agriculture, Directorate of Economics and Statistics, Statistics at a Glance.

India has also removed most quantitative controls on agricultural exports since the late 1990s, but export controls are not restricted by the terms of the AoA, and India continues to impose bans and quotas on exports of agricultural commodities to meet domestic price policy goals. Recent examples include bans on export of rice, wheat, and corn in order to ensure stable domestic prices when global process rose sharply in 2007 and 2008.

India also provides an array of policy incentives aimed at promoting exports of agricultural commodities, including the following:

  • Import duty reductions or drawbacks for goods needed to produce processed products for export.
  • Government support for domestic marketing and transport costs for exported products, consistent with World Trade Organization rules.
  • Government support for agroprocessing zones to produce goods for export.

Domestic Agricultural Market Regulation and Investment

Despite accelerating growth in the overall economy, rising consumer demand, and supportive price and subsidy policies, growth and investment in Indian agriculture and agribusiness have remained weak since the early 1990s. There is evidence that numerous domestic policy interventions, along with weak infrastructure and limited institutional support for agricultural markets, have been a deterrent to new investment by agribusinesses and farmers. An array of central and state government policy interventions in domestic agricultural markets and industries have created disincentives and risks for investors in agribusiness, particularly larger scale and vertically integrated agribusiness enterprises.

Interventions have included movement, storage, and private marketing restrictions for agricultural commodities, scale restrictions on agribusiness firms, high taxes on processed products, relatively high cost credit, and complex food laws. The climate for private investment is also shaped by weak transport and power infrastructure and lack of key market services, such as market information, risk management tools, and grading and inspection systems, which affect the private costs and returns of new investments. For farmers, disincentives have included trade and price policies that, despite MSPs, maintained relatively low domestic prices for many farm commodities, inefficient markets that dampen returns to growers, and the limited availability of public and private marketing services. Onfarm investment may also be constrained by India's large number of small and marginal farmers—accounting for about 39 percent of farm land—who often have limited access to input and output markets and more limited investment options.

Since 2000, there is evidence that the policy environment is improving, and that investment in agriculture and agribusiness is beginning to show stronger growth. Aside from rising MSPs and input subsidies, a number of central and state policy changes appear to be stimulating more private investment. Recent changes include:

  • Restrictions on private movement and storage on farm commodities are becoming less common.
  • Restrictions that limited many types of agricultural processing to small-scale firms have been largely removed.
  • State marketing laws are being changed to permit development of private marketing channels.
  • Taxes on processed agricultural products have been reduced and simplified.
  • A new unified food law will simplify development of food processing industries.

Although power, transport, and other infrastructure problems will likely be solved only in the longer term, there is evidence that private investment is on the rise. Recent private investment activity in food marketing ventures oriented toward development of supply chains and “front end” retail outlets represents a major surge in private investment, as well as a turnaround in investor confidence in the future policy environment in agriculture and agribusiness.

Top of page

More Information

Additional information on India's agricultural and agricultural trade policies are available from:

 

For more information, contact: Maurice R. Landes

Web administration: webadmin@ers.usda.gov

Updated date: January 12, 2009